Consider a duopoly market, where two firms sell differentiated products, which are imperfect substitutes. The market can be modelled as a static price competition game, similar to a linear city model. The two firms choose prices p1 and P2 simultaneously. The derived demand functions for the two firms are: D1 (P1, P2) = S(;+2P1)and D2 (P1, P2)= S(;+P2), where S > 0 and the parameter t> 0 measures the 2t 2t degree of product differentiation. Both firms have constant marginal cost c> 0 for production. (a) Derive the Nash equilibrium of this game, including the prices, outputs and profit of the two firms. (b) From the demand functions, qq= D¿ (pi , p¡ )= S(÷+Pi), derive the residual inverse demand functions: Pi = P; (qi , p¡) (work out: Pt (q; , P¡)). Show that for t > 0, P¿(q; , P¡) is downward 2t aP: (qt »Pj) . sloping, i.e., < 0. Argue that, taking p; 2 0 as given, firm "i" is like a monopolist facing a 'be residual inverse demand, and the optimal q; (which equates marginal revenue and marginal cost) or pi makes Pį = (qi , Pj) = Pi > c, i.e., firm į has market power.
Consider a duopoly market, where two firms sell differentiated products, which are imperfect substitutes. The market can be modelled as a static price competition game, similar to a linear city model. The two firms choose prices p1 and P2 simultaneously. The derived demand functions for the two firms are: D1 (P1, P2) = S(;+2P1)and D2 (P1, P2)= S(;+P2), where S > 0 and the parameter t> 0 measures the 2t 2t degree of product differentiation. Both firms have constant marginal cost c> 0 for production. (a) Derive the Nash equilibrium of this game, including the prices, outputs and profit of the two firms. (b) From the demand functions, qq= D¿ (pi , p¡ )= S(÷+Pi), derive the residual inverse demand functions: Pi = P; (qi , p¡) (work out: Pt (q; , P¡)). Show that for t > 0, P¿(q; , P¡) is downward 2t aP: (qt »Pj) . sloping, i.e., < 0. Argue that, taking p; 2 0 as given, firm "i" is like a monopolist facing a 'be residual inverse demand, and the optimal q; (which equates marginal revenue and marginal cost) or pi makes Pį = (qi , Pj) = Pi > c, i.e., firm į has market power.
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Related questions
Question

Transcribed Image Text:Consider a duopoly market, where two firms sell differentiated products, which are imperfect substitutes.
The market can be modelled as a static price competition game, similar to a linear city model. The two
firms choose prices p, and p2 simultaneously. The derived demand functions for the two firms are: D1
(P1, P2) = SG+P1)and D2 (P1, P2)= S(;+-P2), where S > 0 and the parameter t > 0 measures the
2t
2t
degree of product differentiation. Both firms have constant marginal cost c> 0 for production.
(a) Derive the Nash equilibrium of this game, including the prices, outputs and profit of the two firms.
(b) From the demand functions, qi= D¡ (p; , p¡ )= SG+P), derive the residual inverse demand
functions: p; = P; (qi , p¡) (work out: P; (qi , P;)). Show that for t > 0, P;(qi , P;) is downward
2t
aPi (qi ,Pj) .
sloping, i.e.,
< 0. Argue that, taking p; 20 as given, firm "i" is like a monopolist facing a
residual inverse demand, and the optimal q; (which equates marginal revenue and marginal cost)
or pi makes P; = (qi , Pi) = Pi > c, i.e., firm į has market power.
%3D
(c) Calculate the limits of the equilibrium prices and profit as t → 0 ? What is P; (qi , p;) as t → 0? Is
it downward sloping? Argue that the Bertrand Paradox (i.e., the prediction of the static Bertrand
duopoly model, where p *1 =p *2 = c) holds only in the extreme case of t = 0
Expert Solution

This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
This is a popular solution!
Trending now
This is a popular solution!
Step by step
Solved in 2 steps with 4 images

Follow-up Questions
Read through expert solutions to related follow-up questions below.
Follow-up Question
Why is (P2-P1/2T) and (P1-P2/2T) not multiplied by S for the q1 and q2 equations in the first line?
Solution
Follow-up Question
I cannot figure out how the equation goes from q1 = D1 (p1; p2) = S(1/2 + (p2-p1/2t)) to q1 = S/2 +(p2-p1/2t)
why is S not in the numerator of both terms? i.e. q1 = S/2 + S(p2-p1/2t)
Solution
Follow-up Question

Transcribed Image Text:Consider a duopoly market, where two firms sell differentiated products, which are imperfect substitutes.
The market can be modelled as a static price competition game, similar to a linear city model. The two
firms choose prices p₁ and p2₂ simultaneously. The derived demand functions for the two firms are: D₁
(P₁, P2) = S(+ P2²-P₁) and D₂ (P₁, P2)= S(+²₁=P²), where S> 0 and the parameter t > 0 measures the
2t
2t
degree of product differentiation. Both firms have constant marginal cost c> 0 for production.
(a) Derive the Nash equilibrium of this game, including the prices, outputs and profit of the two firms.
2t
(b) From the demand functions, qi= Di (Pi, Pj )= S(+ PP¹), derive the residual inverse demand
functions: P₁ = Pi (qi, Pj) (work out: Pi (qi, Pj)). Show that for t > 0, Pi(qi, Pj) is downward
OPi (qi Pj)
sloping, i.e.,
<0. Argue that, taking p; ≥ 0 as given, firm "i" is like a monopolist facing a
residual inverse demand, and the optimal qi (which equates marginal revenue and marginal cost)
or pi makes P₁ = (qi, Pj) = pi > c, i.e., firm i has market power.
əqi
O
⠀
(c) Calculate the limits of the equilibrium prices and profit as t → 0 ? What is Pi (qi, Pj) as t → 0? Is
it downward sloping? Argue that the Bertrand Paradox (i.e., the prediction of the static Bertrand
duopoly model, where p *₁ =p *2 = c) holds only in the extreme case of t = 0
Solution
Knowledge Booster
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.Recommended textbooks for you


Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON

Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON


Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON

Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON

Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education