Consider a 2-good, 2-agent pure exchange economy where there are 10 units of each good and preferences are represented by DA, UB R30 →R where UA (XA) = 2XA1 + XA2 and uB (XB) = XB1 + 2XB2- Which 2 of the following 8 options are true: There are initial endowments from which we can have a Walrasian Equilibrium with prices p = (1, 0). O The only Pareto efficient allocation is XA = (10, 0), XB = (0, 10). O Every Pareto efficient allocation can be supported as a Walrasian Equilibrium after some reallocation of resources. We cannot apply the First Welfare Theorem because preferences violate local non-satiation. The allocation XA = (5, 10), XB = (5, 0) is Pareto efficient.
Consider a 2-good, 2-agent pure exchange economy where there are 10 units of each good and preferences are represented by DA, UB R30 →R where UA (XA) = 2XA1 + XA2 and uB (XB) = XB1 + 2XB2- Which 2 of the following 8 options are true: There are initial endowments from which we can have a Walrasian Equilibrium with prices p = (1, 0). O The only Pareto efficient allocation is XA = (10, 0), XB = (0, 10). O Every Pareto efficient allocation can be supported as a Walrasian Equilibrium after some reallocation of resources. We cannot apply the First Welfare Theorem because preferences violate local non-satiation. The allocation XA = (5, 10), XB = (5, 0) is Pareto efficient.
Chapter13: General Equilibrium And Welfare
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 13.5P
Related questions
Question
![Consider a 2-good, 2-agent pure exchange economy where there are 10 units of each good and preferences are represented by UA, UB:
RR where uA (XA) = 2XA1 + XA2 and uB (XB) = XB1 + 2XB2-
Which 2 of the following 8 options are true:
There are initial endowments from which we can have a Walrasian Equilibrium with prices p = (1, 0).
O The only Pareto efficient allocation is XA = (10, 0), XB = (0, 10).
Every Pareto efficient allocation can be supported as a Walrasian Equilibrium after some reallocation of resources.
We cannot apply the First Welfare Theorem because preferences violate local non-satiation.
The allocation XA = (5, 10), XB = (5, 0) is Pareto efficient.
For all price vectors PER3 we have p1z₁ + P2z2 = 0 where z; is the excess demand of good i € {1, 2}.
O Preferences of both players satisfy strict convexity.
At initial endowment eA= (5, 5), eg = (5, 5), there is a Walrasian Equilibrium with prices p = (1, 2).](/v2/_next/image?url=https%3A%2F%2Fcontent.bartleby.com%2Fqna-images%2Fquestion%2F5a7d6291-bcbd-4d13-86a4-a5f4e32dd072%2F8c067373-5bad-42b4-96d0-41249b7147c7%2Fxqkefd_processed.png&w=3840&q=75)
Transcribed Image Text:Consider a 2-good, 2-agent pure exchange economy where there are 10 units of each good and preferences are represented by UA, UB:
RR where uA (XA) = 2XA1 + XA2 and uB (XB) = XB1 + 2XB2-
Which 2 of the following 8 options are true:
There are initial endowments from which we can have a Walrasian Equilibrium with prices p = (1, 0).
O The only Pareto efficient allocation is XA = (10, 0), XB = (0, 10).
Every Pareto efficient allocation can be supported as a Walrasian Equilibrium after some reallocation of resources.
We cannot apply the First Welfare Theorem because preferences violate local non-satiation.
The allocation XA = (5, 10), XB = (5, 0) is Pareto efficient.
For all price vectors PER3 we have p1z₁ + P2z2 = 0 where z; is the excess demand of good i € {1, 2}.
O Preferences of both players satisfy strict convexity.
At initial endowment eA= (5, 5), eg = (5, 5), there is a Walrasian Equilibrium with prices p = (1, 2).
Expert Solution
![](/static/compass_v2/shared-icons/check-mark.png)
This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
Step by step
Solved in 2 steps
![Blurred answer](/static/compass_v2/solution-images/blurred-answer.jpg)
Knowledge Booster
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.Recommended textbooks for you
![Economics (MindTap Course List)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337617383/9781337617383_smallCoverImage.gif)
Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781337617383
Author:
Roger A. Arnold
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Macroeconomics](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337617390/9781337617390_smallCoverImage.gif)
![Economics (MindTap Course List)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337617383/9781337617383_smallCoverImage.gif)
Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781337617383
Author:
Roger A. Arnold
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Macroeconomics](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337617390/9781337617390_smallCoverImage.gif)
![Microeconomics](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337617406/9781337617406_smallCoverImage.gif)
![MACROECONOMICS FOR TODAY](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337613057/9781337613057_smallCoverImage.gif)
![Micro Economics For Today](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337613064/9781337613064_smallCoverImage.gif)