Why is clean air a public good? What does Fig. 18.16 (image provided) show about the willingness to pay for clean air?

ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
14th Edition
ISBN:9780190931919
Author:NEWNAN
Publisher:NEWNAN
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
icon
Related questions
Question

Refer to the image Ch. 18, Example 18.7 - 'The Demand for Clean Air'

Why is clean air a public good? What does Fig. 18.16 (image provided) show about the willingness to pay for clean air?

Figure 18.16 The Demand for Clean Air
Willingness
to Pay
3000
2500
2000
High Income
Middle Income
1500
Low Income
1000
500
012 3 1 5
6
7
9
10
Nitrogen oxide (pphm)
The three curves describe the willingness to pay for clean air (a reduction in the level of nitrogen
oxides) for each of three different households (low income, middle income, and high income). In
general, higher-income households have greater demands for clean air than lower-income
households. Moreover, each household is less willing to pay for clean air as the level of air quality
increases.
The demand curves are upward-sloping because we are measuring pollution rather
than clean air on the horizontal axis. As we would expect, the cleaner the air, the lower
the willingness to pay for more of the good. These differences in the willingness to pay
for clean air vary substantially. In Boston, for example, nitrogen oxide levels ranged
from 3 to 9 pphm. A middle-income household would be willing to pay $800 for a 1
pphm reduction in nitrogen oxide levels when the level is 3 pphm, but the figure would
jump to $2200 for a 1 pphm reduction when the level is 9 pphm.
Note that higher-income households are willing to pay more than lower-income
households to obtain a small improvement in air quality. At low nitrogen oxide levels (3
pphm), the differential between low- and middle-income households is only $200, but it
increases to about $700 at high levels (9 pphm).
With quantitative information about the demand for clean air and separate estimates of
the costs of improving air quality, we can determine whether the benefits of
environmental regulations outweigh the costs. A study by the National Academy of
Sciences of regulations on automobile emissions did just this. The study found that
controls would lower the level of pollutants, such as nitrogen oxides, by approximately
10 percent. The benefit of this 10-percent improvement to all residents of the United
States was calculated to be approximately $2 billion. The study also estimated that it
would cost somewhat less than $2 billion to install pollution control equipment in
automobiles to meet emissions standards. The study concluded, therefore, that the
benefits of the regulations did outweigh the costs.
a
Transcribed Image Text:Figure 18.16 The Demand for Clean Air Willingness to Pay 3000 2500 2000 High Income Middle Income 1500 Low Income 1000 500 012 3 1 5 6 7 9 10 Nitrogen oxide (pphm) The three curves describe the willingness to pay for clean air (a reduction in the level of nitrogen oxides) for each of three different households (low income, middle income, and high income). In general, higher-income households have greater demands for clean air than lower-income households. Moreover, each household is less willing to pay for clean air as the level of air quality increases. The demand curves are upward-sloping because we are measuring pollution rather than clean air on the horizontal axis. As we would expect, the cleaner the air, the lower the willingness to pay for more of the good. These differences in the willingness to pay for clean air vary substantially. In Boston, for example, nitrogen oxide levels ranged from 3 to 9 pphm. A middle-income household would be willing to pay $800 for a 1 pphm reduction in nitrogen oxide levels when the level is 3 pphm, but the figure would jump to $2200 for a 1 pphm reduction when the level is 9 pphm. Note that higher-income households are willing to pay more than lower-income households to obtain a small improvement in air quality. At low nitrogen oxide levels (3 pphm), the differential between low- and middle-income households is only $200, but it increases to about $700 at high levels (9 pphm). With quantitative information about the demand for clean air and separate estimates of the costs of improving air quality, we can determine whether the benefits of environmental regulations outweigh the costs. A study by the National Academy of Sciences of regulations on automobile emissions did just this. The study found that controls would lower the level of pollutants, such as nitrogen oxides, by approximately 10 percent. The benefit of this 10-percent improvement to all residents of the United States was calculated to be approximately $2 billion. The study also estimated that it would cost somewhat less than $2 billion to install pollution control equipment in automobiles to meet emissions standards. The study concluded, therefore, that the benefits of the regulations did outweigh the costs. a
Example 18.7
The Demand for Clean Air
In Example 4.6 we used the demand curve for clean air to calculate the benefits of a
cleaner environment. Now let's examine the public-good characteristics of clean air.
Many factors, including the weather, driving patterns, and industrial emissions,
determine a region's air quality. Any effort to clean up the air will generally improve air
quality throughout the region. As a result, clean air is nonexclusive: It is difficult to stop
any one person from enjoying it. Clean air is also nonrival: My enjoyment does not
inhibit yours.
Because clean air is a public good, there is no market and no observable price at which
people are willing to trade clean air for other commodities. Fortunately, we can infer
people's willingness to pay for clean air from the housing market-households will pay
more for a home located in an area with good air quality than for an otherwise identical
home in an area with poor air quality.
Let's look at the estimates of the demand for clean air obtained from a statistical
analysis of housing data for the Boston metropolitan area. 25 The analysis correlates
housing prices with the quality of air and other characteristics of the houses and their
neighborhoods. Figure 18.16 shows three demand curves in which the value put on
clean air depends on the level of nitrogen oxides and on income. The horizontal axis
measures the level of air pollution in terms of parts per hundred million (pphm) of
nitrogen oxide in the air. The vertical axis measures each household's willingness to pay
for a one-part-per-hundred-million reduction in the nitrogen oxide level.
Transcribed Image Text:Example 18.7 The Demand for Clean Air In Example 4.6 we used the demand curve for clean air to calculate the benefits of a cleaner environment. Now let's examine the public-good characteristics of clean air. Many factors, including the weather, driving patterns, and industrial emissions, determine a region's air quality. Any effort to clean up the air will generally improve air quality throughout the region. As a result, clean air is nonexclusive: It is difficult to stop any one person from enjoying it. Clean air is also nonrival: My enjoyment does not inhibit yours. Because clean air is a public good, there is no market and no observable price at which people are willing to trade clean air for other commodities. Fortunately, we can infer people's willingness to pay for clean air from the housing market-households will pay more for a home located in an area with good air quality than for an otherwise identical home in an area with poor air quality. Let's look at the estimates of the demand for clean air obtained from a statistical analysis of housing data for the Boston metropolitan area. 25 The analysis correlates housing prices with the quality of air and other characteristics of the houses and their neighborhoods. Figure 18.16 shows three demand curves in which the value put on clean air depends on the level of nitrogen oxides and on income. The horizontal axis measures the level of air pollution in terms of parts per hundred million (pphm) of nitrogen oxide in the air. The vertical axis measures each household's willingness to pay for a one-part-per-hundred-million reduction in the nitrogen oxide level.
Expert Solution
steps

Step by step

Solved in 4 steps

Blurred answer
Knowledge Booster
Clean Air Act
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.
Similar questions
  • SEE MORE QUESTIONS
Recommended textbooks for you
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
Economics
ISBN:
9780190931919
Author:
NEWNAN
Publisher:
Oxford University Press
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education