2. The standard model of consumer behavior assumes that income is exogenous. Of course, a person's income usually depends upon the number of hours the individual works. Suppose that an individual has 7 hours each day which can be allocated toward working time, H, or leisure time, L—that is, T = H + L. The individual earns w dollars for each hour worked. Then the individual's income is M + wH where M denotes any non-labor income. The individual has preferences over leisure time, L, and a consumption good, X, which can be represented by a quasi-concave utility function, U(X, L). The consumption good, X, can be purchased at the price Px. The individual seeks to maximize the utility subject to the constraints on time and money.
2. The standard model of consumer behavior assumes that income is exogenous. Of course, a person's income usually depends upon the number of hours the individual works. Suppose that an individual has 7 hours each day which can be allocated toward working time, H, or leisure time, L—that is, T = H + L. The individual earns w dollars for each hour worked. Then the individual's income is M + wH where M denotes any non-labor income. The individual has preferences over leisure time, L, and a consumption good, X, which can be represented by a quasi-concave utility function, U(X, L). The consumption good, X, can be purchased at the price Px. The individual seeks to maximize the utility subject to the constraints on time and money.
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Related questions
Question
![2. The standard model of consumer behavior assumes that income is exogenous. Of
course, a person's income usually depends upon the number of hours the individual
works. Suppose that an individual has T hours each day which can be allocated
toward working time, H, or leisure time, L-that is, T = H + L. The individual earns
w dollars for each hour worked. Then the individual's income is M + wH where M
denotes any non-labor income. The individual has preferences over leisure time, L,
and a consumption good, X, which can be represented by a quasi-concave utility
function, U(X, L). The consumption good, X, can be purchased at the price Px. The
individual seeks to maximize the utility subject to the constraints on time and money.
(1) Formulate the individual's problem as an optimization problem with two
constraints a time constraint and a money constraint. Derive the first-order
conditions. Give an economic interpretation of the Lagrange multipliers.
(2) The two-constraints problem can be reduced to a one-constraint problem by
substituting the time constraint into the money constraint. Formulate the choice of
X and L as a one-constraint problem. Derive the first-order conditions and
compare with the first-order conditions from (1).
(3) Use comparative statics (in words) to determine whether or not an individual wil1
increase the number of hours worked in response to an increase in the wage rate.
Draw a diagram to illustrate the income and substitution effects of an increase in
the wage rate on the number of hours worked.](/v2/_next/image?url=https%3A%2F%2Fcontent.bartleby.com%2Fqna-images%2Fquestion%2Fc67afd47-73a6-45ab-b513-dac9a3557eea%2F94f721e9-7a29-4ee9-8256-9909957fb75d%2Fm191glp_processed.png&w=3840&q=75)
Transcribed Image Text:2. The standard model of consumer behavior assumes that income is exogenous. Of
course, a person's income usually depends upon the number of hours the individual
works. Suppose that an individual has T hours each day which can be allocated
toward working time, H, or leisure time, L-that is, T = H + L. The individual earns
w dollars for each hour worked. Then the individual's income is M + wH where M
denotes any non-labor income. The individual has preferences over leisure time, L,
and a consumption good, X, which can be represented by a quasi-concave utility
function, U(X, L). The consumption good, X, can be purchased at the price Px. The
individual seeks to maximize the utility subject to the constraints on time and money.
(1) Formulate the individual's problem as an optimization problem with two
constraints a time constraint and a money constraint. Derive the first-order
conditions. Give an economic interpretation of the Lagrange multipliers.
(2) The two-constraints problem can be reduced to a one-constraint problem by
substituting the time constraint into the money constraint. Formulate the choice of
X and L as a one-constraint problem. Derive the first-order conditions and
compare with the first-order conditions from (1).
(3) Use comparative statics (in words) to determine whether or not an individual wil1
increase the number of hours worked in response to an increase in the wage rate.
Draw a diagram to illustrate the income and substitution effects of an increase in
the wage rate on the number of hours worked.
Expert Solution
![](/static/compass_v2/shared-icons/check-mark.png)
This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
This is a popular solution!
Trending now
This is a popular solution!
Step by step
Solved in 4 steps with 4 images
![Blurred answer](/static/compass_v2/solution-images/blurred-answer.jpg)
Knowledge Booster
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.Recommended textbooks for you
![ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS](https://compass-isbn-assets.s3.amazonaws.com/isbn_cover_images/9780190931919/9780190931919_smallCoverImage.gif)
![Principles of Economics (12th Edition)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9780134078779/9780134078779_smallCoverImage.gif)
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
![Engineering Economy (17th Edition)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9780134870069/9780134870069_smallCoverImage.gif)
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
![ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS](https://compass-isbn-assets.s3.amazonaws.com/isbn_cover_images/9780190931919/9780190931919_smallCoverImage.gif)
![Principles of Economics (12th Edition)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9780134078779/9780134078779_smallCoverImage.gif)
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
![Engineering Economy (17th Edition)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9780134870069/9780134870069_smallCoverImage.gif)
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
![Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781305585126/9781305585126_smallCoverImage.gif)
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337106665/9781337106665_smallCoverImage.gif)
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781259290619/9781259290619_smallCoverImage.gif)
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education