11:45 Fri Apr 4 Would+You+Take+the+Bird+in+the+Hand Even when it actually hurts you on aver to take the gamble, the smart people, the high-scoring people, actually like it more,' Professor Frederick said in an interview. Almost a third of high scorers preferred a 1 percent chance of $5,000 to a sure $60. They are also more patient, particularly when the difference, and the implied interest rate, is large. Choosing $3,400 this month over $3,800 next month implies an annual discount rate of 280 percent. Yet only 35 percent of low scorers those who missed every question said they would wait, while 60 percent of high scorers preferred the later, bigger payoff. Men and women also show different results. "Expressed loosely," he writes, "being smart makes women patient and makes men take more risks." High-scoring women show slightly more willingness to wait than high-scoring men, while the differences in risk-taking are much larger. High-scoring women are about as willing to gamble as low- scoring men, while low-scoring women are even more risk-averse For instance, 80 percent of high-scoring men would pick a 15 percent chance of $1 million over a sure $500, compared with only 38 percent of high-scoring women, 40 percent of low-scoring men and 25 percent of low-scoring women. The connection between cognition and risk preferences challenges some of the "prospect theory" developed from the pioneering work of Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. They observed that people would accept larger risks to avoid losses than to achieve gains, even when the two choices were mathematically equivalent. The same person might take a sure $100 instead of a 50 percent chance of $300, yet prefer a 50 percent chance of losing $300 rather than a sure $100 loss. This result, which has implications for investment and insurance, is one of the major findings of behavioral economics. Although prospect theory "is spectacularly true" for the low-scoring group, Professor Frederick writes, high scorers treat potential gains and potential losses about the same. Psychology studies often find that small differences in wording seem to produce large differences in survey answers. But since these experiments are usually done on college campuses using students, the real difference may lie elsewhere. Maybe, suggested Professor Frederick in the interview, "it's because one study was done at University of Toledo" where the mean score on his test was 0.57 out of a possible 3 "and one study was done at Princeton," where the mean was 1.63. The test groups may not really be the same. "Most researchers are finding that subtle differences in framing cause different preferences," he said, "but it might just be that these people are a whole lot smarter on average than these other people, and that's why you're getting these results." The correct answers, by the way, are 5 cents, 5 minutes, and 47 days. VPN 86% Done 11:46 Fri Apr 4 Would+You+Take+the+Bird+in+the+Hand WOULD you rather have $1,000 for sure or a 90 percent chance of $5,000? A guaranteed $1,000 or a 75 percent chance of $4,000? In economic theory, questions like these have no right or wrong answers. Even if a gamble is mathematically more valuable a 75 percent chance of $4,000 has an expected value of $3,000, for instance someone may still prefer a sure thing. People have different tastes for risk, just as they have different tastes for ice cream or paint colors. The same is true for waiting: Would you rather have $400 now or $100 every year for 10 years? How about $3,400 this month or $3,800 next month? Different people will answer differently. Economists generally accept those differences without further explanation, while decision researchers tend to focus on average behavior. In decision research, individual differences "are regarded as a nuisance as just another source of 'unexplained' variance," Shane Frederick, a management science professor at the Sloan School of Management at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, wrote. in "Cognitive Reflection and Decision Making." The article is published in the Fall 2005 issue of The Journal of Economic Perspectives, which includes a special section of articles devoted to "cognition, brain science and economics." (The article is available at mit.edu/people/shanefre/ publications.htm.) Professor Frederick discovered striking systematic patterns in how people answer questions about risk and patience, including those above. This short problem-solving test, he found, predicts a lot: 1) A bat and a ball cost $1.10 in total. The bat costs $1 more than the ball. How much does the ball cost? 2) If it takes five machines five minutes to make five widgets, how long would it take 100 machines to make 100 widgets? 3) In a lake, there is a patch of lily pads. Every day, the patch doubles in size. If it takes 48 days for the patch to cover the entire lake, how long would it take for the patch to cover half the lake? The test measures not just the ability to solve math problems but the willingness to reflect on and check your answers. (Scores have a 0.44 correlation with math SAT scores, where 1.00 would be exact.) The questions all have intuitive answers wrong ones. Professor Frederick gave his "cognitive reflection test" to nearly 3,500 respondents, mostly students at universities including M.I.T., the University of Michigan and Bowling Green University. Participants also answered a survey about how they would choose between various financial payoffs, as well as time-oriented questions like how much they would pay to get a book delivered overnight. Getting the math problems right predicts nothing about most tastes including whether someone prefers annies or oranges VPN 86% Done
11:45 Fri Apr 4 Would+You+Take+the+Bird+in+the+Hand Even when it actually hurts you on aver to take the gamble, the smart people, the high-scoring people, actually like it more,' Professor Frederick said in an interview. Almost a third of high scorers preferred a 1 percent chance of $5,000 to a sure $60. They are also more patient, particularly when the difference, and the implied interest rate, is large. Choosing $3,400 this month over $3,800 next month implies an annual discount rate of 280 percent. Yet only 35 percent of low scorers those who missed every question said they would wait, while 60 percent of high scorers preferred the later, bigger payoff. Men and women also show different results. "Expressed loosely," he writes, "being smart makes women patient and makes men take more risks." High-scoring women show slightly more willingness to wait than high-scoring men, while the differences in risk-taking are much larger. High-scoring women are about as willing to gamble as low- scoring men, while low-scoring women are even more risk-averse For instance, 80 percent of high-scoring men would pick a 15 percent chance of $1 million over a sure $500, compared with only 38 percent of high-scoring women, 40 percent of low-scoring men and 25 percent of low-scoring women. The connection between cognition and risk preferences challenges some of the "prospect theory" developed from the pioneering work of Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. They observed that people would accept larger risks to avoid losses than to achieve gains, even when the two choices were mathematically equivalent. The same person might take a sure $100 instead of a 50 percent chance of $300, yet prefer a 50 percent chance of losing $300 rather than a sure $100 loss. This result, which has implications for investment and insurance, is one of the major findings of behavioral economics. Although prospect theory "is spectacularly true" for the low-scoring group, Professor Frederick writes, high scorers treat potential gains and potential losses about the same. Psychology studies often find that small differences in wording seem to produce large differences in survey answers. But since these experiments are usually done on college campuses using students, the real difference may lie elsewhere. Maybe, suggested Professor Frederick in the interview, "it's because one study was done at University of Toledo" where the mean score on his test was 0.57 out of a possible 3 "and one study was done at Princeton," where the mean was 1.63. The test groups may not really be the same. "Most researchers are finding that subtle differences in framing cause different preferences," he said, "but it might just be that these people are a whole lot smarter on average than these other people, and that's why you're getting these results." The correct answers, by the way, are 5 cents, 5 minutes, and 47 days. VPN 86% Done 11:46 Fri Apr 4 Would+You+Take+the+Bird+in+the+Hand WOULD you rather have $1,000 for sure or a 90 percent chance of $5,000? A guaranteed $1,000 or a 75 percent chance of $4,000? In economic theory, questions like these have no right or wrong answers. Even if a gamble is mathematically more valuable a 75 percent chance of $4,000 has an expected value of $3,000, for instance someone may still prefer a sure thing. People have different tastes for risk, just as they have different tastes for ice cream or paint colors. The same is true for waiting: Would you rather have $400 now or $100 every year for 10 years? How about $3,400 this month or $3,800 next month? Different people will answer differently. Economists generally accept those differences without further explanation, while decision researchers tend to focus on average behavior. In decision research, individual differences "are regarded as a nuisance as just another source of 'unexplained' variance," Shane Frederick, a management science professor at the Sloan School of Management at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, wrote. in "Cognitive Reflection and Decision Making." The article is published in the Fall 2005 issue of The Journal of Economic Perspectives, which includes a special section of articles devoted to "cognition, brain science and economics." (The article is available at mit.edu/people/shanefre/ publications.htm.) Professor Frederick discovered striking systematic patterns in how people answer questions about risk and patience, including those above. This short problem-solving test, he found, predicts a lot: 1) A bat and a ball cost $1.10 in total. The bat costs $1 more than the ball. How much does the ball cost? 2) If it takes five machines five minutes to make five widgets, how long would it take 100 machines to make 100 widgets? 3) In a lake, there is a patch of lily pads. Every day, the patch doubles in size. If it takes 48 days for the patch to cover the entire lake, how long would it take for the patch to cover half the lake? The test measures not just the ability to solve math problems but the willingness to reflect on and check your answers. (Scores have a 0.44 correlation with math SAT scores, where 1.00 would be exact.) The questions all have intuitive answers wrong ones. Professor Frederick gave his "cognitive reflection test" to nearly 3,500 respondents, mostly students at universities including M.I.T., the University of Michigan and Bowling Green University. Participants also answered a survey about how they would choose between various financial payoffs, as well as time-oriented questions like how much they would pay to get a book delivered overnight. Getting the math problems right predicts nothing about most tastes including whether someone prefers annies or oranges VPN 86% Done
Chapter7: Uncertainty
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 7.7P
Related questions
Question
Explain Professor Frederick's "cognitive reflection" test.

Transcribed Image Text:11:45 Fri Apr 4
Would+You+Take+the+Bird+in+the+Hand
Even when it actually hurts you on aver
to take the gamble,
the smart people, the high-scoring people, actually like it more,'
Professor Frederick said in an interview. Almost a third of high
scorers preferred a 1 percent chance of $5,000 to a sure $60.
They are also more patient, particularly when the difference, and
the implied interest rate, is large. Choosing $3,400 this month
over $3,800 next month implies an annual discount rate of 280
percent. Yet only 35 percent of low scorers those who missed
every question said they would wait, while 60 percent of high
scorers preferred the later, bigger payoff.
Men and women also show different results. "Expressed loosely,"
he writes, "being smart makes women patient and makes men
take more risks."
High-scoring women show slightly more willingness to wait than
high-scoring men, while the differences in risk-taking are much
larger. High-scoring women are about as willing to gamble as low-
scoring men, while low-scoring women are even more risk-averse
For instance, 80 percent of high-scoring men would pick a 15
percent chance of $1 million over a sure $500, compared with
only 38 percent of high-scoring women, 40 percent of low-scoring
men and 25 percent of low-scoring women.
The connection between cognition and risk preferences challenges
some of the "prospect theory" developed from the pioneering
work of Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. They observed that
people would accept larger risks to avoid losses than to achieve
gains, even when the two choices were mathematically
equivalent. The same person might take a sure $100 instead of a
50 percent chance of $300, yet prefer a 50 percent chance of
losing $300 rather than a sure $100 loss.
This result, which has implications for investment and insurance,
is one of the major findings of behavioral economics. Although
prospect theory "is spectacularly true" for the low-scoring group,
Professor Frederick writes, high scorers treat potential gains and
potential losses about the same.
Psychology studies often find that small differences in wording
seem to produce large differences in survey answers. But since
these experiments are usually done on college campuses using
students, the real difference may lie elsewhere.
Maybe, suggested Professor Frederick in the interview, "it's
because one study was done at University of Toledo" where the
mean score on his test was 0.57 out of a possible 3 "and one
study was done at Princeton," where the mean was 1.63. The test
groups may not really be the same.
"Most researchers are finding that subtle differences in framing
cause different preferences," he said, "but it might just be that
these people are a whole lot smarter on average than these other
people, and that's why you're getting these results."
The correct answers, by the way, are 5 cents, 5 minutes, and 47
days.
VPN 86%
Done

Transcribed Image Text:11:46 Fri Apr 4
Would+You+Take+the+Bird+in+the+Hand
WOULD you rather have $1,000 for sure or a 90 percent chance
of $5,000? A guaranteed $1,000 or a 75 percent chance of
$4,000?
In economic theory, questions like these have no right or wrong
answers. Even if a gamble is mathematically more valuable a 75
percent chance of $4,000 has an expected value of $3,000, for
instance someone may still prefer a sure thing.
People have different tastes for risk, just as they have different
tastes for ice cream or paint colors. The same is true for waiting:
Would you rather have $400 now or $100 every year for 10
years? How about $3,400 this month or $3,800 next month?
Different people will answer differently.
Economists generally accept those differences without further
explanation, while decision researchers tend to focus on average
behavior.
In decision research, individual differences "are regarded as a
nuisance as just another source of 'unexplained' variance," Shane
Frederick, a management science professor at the Sloan School of
Management at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, wrote.
in "Cognitive Reflection and Decision Making." The article is
published in the Fall 2005 issue of The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, which includes a special section of articles devoted
to "cognition, brain science and economics." (The article is
available at mit.edu/people/shanefre/ publications.htm.)
Professor Frederick discovered striking systematic patterns in how
people answer questions about risk and patience, including those
above. This short problem-solving test, he found, predicts a lot:
1) A bat and a ball cost $1.10 in total. The bat costs $1 more
than the ball. How much does the ball cost?
2) If it takes five machines five minutes to make five widgets,
how long would it take 100 machines to make 100 widgets?
3) In a lake, there is a patch of lily pads. Every day, the patch
doubles in size. If it takes 48 days for the patch to cover the
entire lake, how long would it take for the patch to cover half the
lake?
The test measures not just the ability to solve math problems but
the willingness to reflect on and check your answers. (Scores
have a 0.44 correlation with math SAT scores, where 1.00 would
be exact.) The questions all have intuitive answers wrong ones.
Professor Frederick gave his "cognitive reflection test" to nearly
3,500 respondents, mostly students at universities including
M.I.T., the University of Michigan and Bowling Green University.
Participants also answered a survey about how they would choose
between various financial payoffs, as well as time-oriented
questions like how much they would pay to get a book delivered
overnight.
Getting the math problems right predicts nothing about most
tastes including whether someone prefers annies or oranges
VPN 86%
Done
Expert Solution

This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
Step by step
Solved in 2 steps

Recommended textbooks for you

Principles of Economics 2e
Economics
ISBN:
9781947172364
Author:
Steven A. Greenlaw; David Shapiro
Publisher:
OpenStax

Essentials of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781337091992
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Principles of Economics 2e
Economics
ISBN:
9781947172364
Author:
Steven A. Greenlaw; David Shapiro
Publisher:
OpenStax

Essentials of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781337091992
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Brief Principles of Macroeconomics (MindTap Cours…
Economics
ISBN:
9781337091985
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Principles of Microeconomics
Economics
ISBN:
9781305156050
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Microeconomics: Private and Public Choice (MindTa…
Economics
ISBN:
9781305506893
Author:
James D. Gwartney, Richard L. Stroup, Russell S. Sobel, David A. Macpherson
Publisher:
Cengage Learning