G G Market Equilibrium: Stability and Time Paths Courtesy of James E. Foster, George Washington University A perfectly competitive market is made up of many buyers and sellers of an economic product, each of whom has no control over the market price. In this model, the overall quantity demanded by the buyers of the product is taken to be a function of the price of the product (among other things) called the demand function. Similarly, the overall quantity supplied by the sellers of the product is a function of the price of the product (among other things) called the supply function. A market is in equilibrium at a price where the quantity demanded is just equal to the quantity supplied. The linear model assumes that the demand and supply functions have the form qa = do – dp and q, = –so + sip, respectively, where p is the market price of the product, qą is the associated quantity demanded, q, is the associated quantity supplied, and do, d1, so, and s1 are all positive constants. The functional forms ensure that the “laws" of downward sloping demand and upward sloping supply are being satisfied. It is easy to show that the equilibrium price is p* = (do + so)/(d1 + s1). Economists typically assume that markets are in equilibrium and justify this assumption with the help of stability arguments. For example, consider the simple price adjustment equation dp A(qa – q,) , dt where A > 0 is a constant indicating the speed of adjustments. This follows the intuitive require- ment that price rises when demand exceeds supply and falls when supply exceeds demand. The market equilibrium is said to be globally stable if, for every initial price level p(0), the price adjustment path p(t) satisfies p(t) → p° as t → ∞. (a) Find the price adjustment path: Substitute the expressions for qa and q, into the price adjustment equation and show that the solution to the resulting differential equation is p(t) = [p(0) – p* ]ed + p*, where c = -X(d, + s1). (b) Is the market equilibrium globally stable? Now consider a model that takes into account the expectations of agents. Let the market demand and supply functions over time t > 0 be given by qalt) = do – dip(1) + d¿p'(t) and q,(t) = –so + sip(t) – s2p'(t) , respectively, where p(t) is the market price of the product, qa(t) is the associated quantity demanded, q,(t) is the associated quantity supplied, and do, d1, d2, so, 81, and s2 are all positive constants. The functional forms ensure that, when faced with an increasing price, demanders will tend to purchase more (before prices rise further) while suppliers will tend to offer less (to take advantage of the higher prices in the future). Now given the above stability argument, we restrict consideration to market clearing time paths p(t) satisfying qa(t) = q,(1), for all t> 0, and explore the evolution of price over time. We say that the market is in dynamic equilibrium if p'(t) = 0 for all t. It is easy to show that the dynamic equilibrium in this model is given by p(t) = p* for all t, where p* is the market equilibrium price defined above. However, many other market clearing time paths are possible. (c) Find a market clearing time path: Equate q.(t) and q,(t) and solve the resulting differen- tial equation p(t) in terms of its initial value po = p(0). (d) Is it true that for any market clearing time path we must have p(t) → p* as t → ∞? (e) If the price p(t) of a product is $5 at t = 0 months and demand and supply functions are modeled as q.(t) = 30 – 2p(t) + 4p'(t) and q,(t) = -20 + p(t) – 6p'(t), what will be the price after 10 months? As t becomes very large? What is happening to p'(t) and how are the expectations of demanders and suppliers evolving?

Advanced Engineering Mathematics
10th Edition
ISBN:9780470458365
Author:Erwin Kreyszig
Publisher:Erwin Kreyszig
Chapter2: Second-order Linear Odes
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1RQ
icon
Related questions
Question

Fundamentals of Differential Equation.

Market Equilibrium: Stability and Time Paths Problem

G
G Market Equilibrium: Stability
and Time Paths
Courtesy of James E. Foster, George Washington University
A perfectly competitive market is made up of many buyers and sellers of an economic product,
each of whom has no control over the market price. In this model, the overall quantity demanded
by the buyers of the product is taken to be a function of the price of the product (among other
things) called the demand function. Similarly, the overall quantity supplied by the sellers of the
product is a function of the price of the product (among other things) called the supply function.
A market is in equilibrium at a price where the quantity demanded is just equal to the quantity
supplied.
The linear model assumes that the demand and supply functions have the form qa = do – dp
and q, = –so + sip, respectively, where p is the market price of the product, qą is the associated
quantity demanded, q, is the associated quantity supplied, and do, d1, so, and s1 are all positive
constants. The functional forms ensure that the “laws" of downward sloping demand and upward
sloping supply are being satisfied. It is easy to show that the equilibrium price is p* =
(do + so)/(d1 + s1).
Economists typically assume that markets are in equilibrium and justify this assumption with
the help of stability arguments. For example, consider the simple price adjustment equation
dp
A(qa – q,) ,
dt
where A > 0 is a constant indicating the speed of adjustments. This follows the intuitive require-
ment that price rises when demand exceeds supply and falls when supply exceeds demand. The
market equilibrium is said to be globally stable if, for every initial price level p(0), the price
adjustment path p(t) satisfies p(t) → p° as t → ∞.
(a) Find the price adjustment path: Substitute the expressions for qa and q, into the price
adjustment equation and show that the solution to the resulting differential equation is
p(t) = [p(0) – p* ]ed + p*, where c = -X(d, + s1).
(b) Is the market equilibrium globally stable?
Now consider a model that takes into account the expectations of agents. Let the market
demand and supply functions over time t > 0 be given by
qalt) = do – dip(1) + d¿p'(t) and q,(t) = –so + sip(t) – s2p'(t) ,
respectively, where p(t) is the market price of the product, qa(t) is the associated quantity
demanded, q,(t) is the associated quantity supplied, and do, d1, d2, so, 81, and s2 are all positive
constants. The functional forms ensure that, when faced with an increasing price, demanders will
tend to purchase more (before prices rise further) while suppliers will tend to offer less (to take
advantage of the higher prices in the future). Now given the above stability argument, we restrict
consideration to market clearing time paths p(t) satisfying qa(t) = q,(1), for all t> 0, and
explore the evolution of price over time. We say that the market is in dynamic equilibrium if
p'(t) = 0 for all t. It is easy to show that the dynamic equilibrium in this model is given by
p(t) = p* for all t, where p* is the market equilibrium price defined above. However, many other
market clearing time paths are possible.
(c) Find a market clearing time path: Equate q.(t) and q,(t) and solve the resulting differen-
tial equation p(t) in terms of its initial value po = p(0).
(d) Is it true that for any market clearing time path we must have p(t) → p* as t → ∞?
(e) If the price p(t) of a product is $5 at t = 0 months and demand and supply functions
are modeled as q.(t) = 30 – 2p(t) + 4p'(t) and q,(t) = -20 + p(t) – 6p'(t), what
will be the price after 10 months? As t becomes very large? What is happening to p'(t)
and how are the expectations of demanders and suppliers evolving?
Transcribed Image Text:G G Market Equilibrium: Stability and Time Paths Courtesy of James E. Foster, George Washington University A perfectly competitive market is made up of many buyers and sellers of an economic product, each of whom has no control over the market price. In this model, the overall quantity demanded by the buyers of the product is taken to be a function of the price of the product (among other things) called the demand function. Similarly, the overall quantity supplied by the sellers of the product is a function of the price of the product (among other things) called the supply function. A market is in equilibrium at a price where the quantity demanded is just equal to the quantity supplied. The linear model assumes that the demand and supply functions have the form qa = do – dp and q, = –so + sip, respectively, where p is the market price of the product, qą is the associated quantity demanded, q, is the associated quantity supplied, and do, d1, so, and s1 are all positive constants. The functional forms ensure that the “laws" of downward sloping demand and upward sloping supply are being satisfied. It is easy to show that the equilibrium price is p* = (do + so)/(d1 + s1). Economists typically assume that markets are in equilibrium and justify this assumption with the help of stability arguments. For example, consider the simple price adjustment equation dp A(qa – q,) , dt where A > 0 is a constant indicating the speed of adjustments. This follows the intuitive require- ment that price rises when demand exceeds supply and falls when supply exceeds demand. The market equilibrium is said to be globally stable if, for every initial price level p(0), the price adjustment path p(t) satisfies p(t) → p° as t → ∞. (a) Find the price adjustment path: Substitute the expressions for qa and q, into the price adjustment equation and show that the solution to the resulting differential equation is p(t) = [p(0) – p* ]ed + p*, where c = -X(d, + s1). (b) Is the market equilibrium globally stable? Now consider a model that takes into account the expectations of agents. Let the market demand and supply functions over time t > 0 be given by qalt) = do – dip(1) + d¿p'(t) and q,(t) = –so + sip(t) – s2p'(t) , respectively, where p(t) is the market price of the product, qa(t) is the associated quantity demanded, q,(t) is the associated quantity supplied, and do, d1, d2, so, 81, and s2 are all positive constants. The functional forms ensure that, when faced with an increasing price, demanders will tend to purchase more (before prices rise further) while suppliers will tend to offer less (to take advantage of the higher prices in the future). Now given the above stability argument, we restrict consideration to market clearing time paths p(t) satisfying qa(t) = q,(1), for all t> 0, and explore the evolution of price over time. We say that the market is in dynamic equilibrium if p'(t) = 0 for all t. It is easy to show that the dynamic equilibrium in this model is given by p(t) = p* for all t, where p* is the market equilibrium price defined above. However, many other market clearing time paths are possible. (c) Find a market clearing time path: Equate q.(t) and q,(t) and solve the resulting differen- tial equation p(t) in terms of its initial value po = p(0). (d) Is it true that for any market clearing time path we must have p(t) → p* as t → ∞? (e) If the price p(t) of a product is $5 at t = 0 months and demand and supply functions are modeled as q.(t) = 30 – 2p(t) + 4p'(t) and q,(t) = -20 + p(t) – 6p'(t), what will be the price after 10 months? As t becomes very large? What is happening to p'(t) and how are the expectations of demanders and suppliers evolving?
Expert Solution
trending now

Trending now

This is a popular solution!

steps

Step by step

Solved in 6 steps with 77 images

Blurred answer
Similar questions
Recommended textbooks for you
Advanced Engineering Mathematics
Advanced Engineering Mathematics
Advanced Math
ISBN:
9780470458365
Author:
Erwin Kreyszig
Publisher:
Wiley, John & Sons, Incorporated
Numerical Methods for Engineers
Numerical Methods for Engineers
Advanced Math
ISBN:
9780073397924
Author:
Steven C. Chapra Dr., Raymond P. Canale
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education
Introductory Mathematics for Engineering Applicat…
Introductory Mathematics for Engineering Applicat…
Advanced Math
ISBN:
9781118141809
Author:
Nathan Klingbeil
Publisher:
WILEY
Mathematics For Machine Technology
Mathematics For Machine Technology
Advanced Math
ISBN:
9781337798310
Author:
Peterson, John.
Publisher:
Cengage Learning,
Basic Technical Mathematics
Basic Technical Mathematics
Advanced Math
ISBN:
9780134437705
Author:
Washington
Publisher:
PEARSON
Topology
Topology
Advanced Math
ISBN:
9780134689517
Author:
Munkres, James R.
Publisher:
Pearson,