Consider two individuals who face an uncertain income, w, that can have two values, 0 and 16, with equal probabilities. The individuals' utility functions are given by: u¹ = w¹/2 and u² = (w¹/2)¹/2. Use THESE utility functions to show that the individual who is more risk averse is willing to pay a higher risk premium.
Consider two individuals who face an uncertain income, w, that can have two values, 0 and 16, with equal probabilities. The individuals' utility functions are given by: u¹ = w¹/2 and u² = (w¹/2)¹/2. Use THESE utility functions to show that the individual who is more risk averse is willing to pay a higher risk premium.
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Related questions
Question
advanced
![Question:
Consider two individuals who face an uncertain income, w, that can have two
values, 0 and 16, with equal probabilities. The individuals' utility functions are
given by: u¹=w¹/2 and u² = (w¹/2)1/2. Use THESE utility functions to show that
the individual who is more risk averse is willing to pay a higher risk premium.
Use below method to answer above question:
3 Attitudes Toward Risk
Consider an individual whose income is given by the random variable w.
Suppose w is distributed according to the distribution function g(w), whose mean and variance are given by
E(w) = w and Var(w) = o².
• Assuming that the individual's preferences satisfy the above assumptions, we can consider her expected utility
function: E[u(w)].
• Compare the two values: E[u(w)] and u[E(w)] = u(w).
• Will she prefer the lottery w (distributed according to the distribution g(w)) or the certain value of w?
● Consider a function of one variable u(w), where w € W.
• Remember the definition of concavity (of course, in the general definition of concavity, we did not restrict
ourselves to functions of one variable):
u(w) is concave if, for any (w₁, W2) E W, we have,
pu(w₁) + (1 − p)u(w₂) ≤ u[pw₁ + (1 − p)w₂] = u[w]
for all 0 < p ≤1
This definition says: "The average of the function is smaller than the function evaluated at the average.
● In our context (of choice under uncertainty), if we think of w as a discrete random variable with two possible
outcomes (n = 2), whose probabilities are p, (1 − p), we have:
pu(w₁) + (1 − p)u(w₂) = E[u(w)]
pw₁ + (1 − p)w2 = E(w)
● Thus, we can write the inequality above as:
E[u(w)] ≤ u[E(w)]
Jensen's Inequality.
• This inequality is a version of what is known as
● It can be generalized to the discrete case with any number of outcomes n > 2 and the continuous case.
(18)
(19)
• Here is the proof for the continuous case:
• Let w be distributed according to the distribution function g(w), whose mean is E(w) = w.
Since u(w) is concave, we know that its graph lies everywhere below all its tangents (equivalently, it lies
everywhere below its supporting lines).
● In other words, for any w and z, we have:
u(w) ≤ u(z) + u'(z)(w – z)](/v2/_next/image?url=https%3A%2F%2Fcontent.bartleby.com%2Fqna-images%2Fquestion%2F09238b20-1e79-43dc-b0a6-3d40e032e374%2F57e9b7a4-553b-47e7-be21-abfdad47d8a8%2Fgs6azre_processed.jpeg&w=3840&q=75)
Transcribed Image Text:Question:
Consider two individuals who face an uncertain income, w, that can have two
values, 0 and 16, with equal probabilities. The individuals' utility functions are
given by: u¹=w¹/2 and u² = (w¹/2)1/2. Use THESE utility functions to show that
the individual who is more risk averse is willing to pay a higher risk premium.
Use below method to answer above question:
3 Attitudes Toward Risk
Consider an individual whose income is given by the random variable w.
Suppose w is distributed according to the distribution function g(w), whose mean and variance are given by
E(w) = w and Var(w) = o².
• Assuming that the individual's preferences satisfy the above assumptions, we can consider her expected utility
function: E[u(w)].
• Compare the two values: E[u(w)] and u[E(w)] = u(w).
• Will she prefer the lottery w (distributed according to the distribution g(w)) or the certain value of w?
● Consider a function of one variable u(w), where w € W.
• Remember the definition of concavity (of course, in the general definition of concavity, we did not restrict
ourselves to functions of one variable):
u(w) is concave if, for any (w₁, W2) E W, we have,
pu(w₁) + (1 − p)u(w₂) ≤ u[pw₁ + (1 − p)w₂] = u[w]
for all 0 < p ≤1
This definition says: "The average of the function is smaller than the function evaluated at the average.
● In our context (of choice under uncertainty), if we think of w as a discrete random variable with two possible
outcomes (n = 2), whose probabilities are p, (1 − p), we have:
pu(w₁) + (1 − p)u(w₂) = E[u(w)]
pw₁ + (1 − p)w2 = E(w)
● Thus, we can write the inequality above as:
E[u(w)] ≤ u[E(w)]
Jensen's Inequality.
• This inequality is a version of what is known as
● It can be generalized to the discrete case with any number of outcomes n > 2 and the continuous case.
(18)
(19)
• Here is the proof for the continuous case:
• Let w be distributed according to the distribution function g(w), whose mean is E(w) = w.
Since u(w) is concave, we know that its graph lies everywhere below all its tangents (equivalently, it lies
everywhere below its supporting lines).
● In other words, for any w and z, we have:
u(w) ≤ u(z) + u'(z)(w – z)
Expert Solution

This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
Step by step
Solved in 4 steps

Knowledge Booster
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.Recommended textbooks for you


Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON

Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON


Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON

Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON

Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education