Consider a variant of the ultimatum game we studied in class in which players have fairness considerations. The timing of the game is as usual. First, player 1 proposes the split (100 – x, x) of a hundred dollars to player 2, where x € [0, 100]. Player 2 observes the split and decides whether to accept (in which case they receive money according to the proposed split) or reject (in which case they both get 0 dollars). But now player i's utility equals to her monetary utility minus the disutility from unfairness proportional to the difference in the monetary outcomes. That is, given a final split (m1, m2), let u1(m1, m2) = m1 – B1(m1 – m2)² uj(m1, m2) = m2 – B2(m1 – m2)², where ß1, ß2 are parameters of the game indicating how strongly players care about fairness. Note that the case we considered in class corresponds to B1 = B = 0.
Consider a variant of the ultimatum game we studied in class in which players have fairness considerations. The timing of the game is as usual. First, player 1 proposes the split (100 – x, x) of a hundred dollars to player 2, where x € [0, 100]. Player 2 observes the split and decides whether to accept (in which case they receive money according to the proposed split) or reject (in which case they both get 0 dollars). But now player i's utility equals to her monetary utility minus the disutility from unfairness proportional to the difference in the monetary outcomes. That is, given a final split (m1, m2), let u1(m1, m2) = m1 – B1(m1 – m2)² uj(m1, m2) = m2 – B2(m1 – m2)², where ß1, ß2 are parameters of the game indicating how strongly players care about fairness. Note that the case we considered in class corresponds to B1 = B = 0.
Chapter8: Game Theory
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 8.7P
Related questions
Question
![Consider a variant of the ultimatum game we studied in class in which players have fairness considerations. The timing of
the game is as usual. First, player 1 proposes the split (100 – x, x) of a hundred dollars to player 2, where x € [0, 100]. Player 2
observes the split and decides whether to accept (in which case they receive money according to the proposed split) or reject
(in which case they both get 0 dollars). But now player i's utility equals to her monetary utility minus the disutility from
unfairness proportional to the difference in the monetary outcomes. That is, given a final split (m1, m2), let
u1(m1, m2) = m1 – B1(m1 -– m2)²
u1(m1, m2) = m2 - B2(m1 – m2)²,
where B1, B2 are parameters of the game indicating how strongly players care about fairness. Note that the case we considered
in class corresponds to ß1 = B2 = 0.](/v2/_next/image?url=https%3A%2F%2Fcontent.bartleby.com%2Fqna-images%2Fquestion%2Fbe960b7b-8746-4256-b957-606edabfae78%2Feccfeaaa-71de-4fe3-856e-a248f0f67050%2Fakqu7of_processed.png&w=3840&q=75)
Transcribed Image Text:Consider a variant of the ultimatum game we studied in class in which players have fairness considerations. The timing of
the game is as usual. First, player 1 proposes the split (100 – x, x) of a hundred dollars to player 2, where x € [0, 100]. Player 2
observes the split and decides whether to accept (in which case they receive money according to the proposed split) or reject
(in which case they both get 0 dollars). But now player i's utility equals to her monetary utility minus the disutility from
unfairness proportional to the difference in the monetary outcomes. That is, given a final split (m1, m2), let
u1(m1, m2) = m1 – B1(m1 -– m2)²
u1(m1, m2) = m2 - B2(m1 – m2)²,
where B1, B2 are parameters of the game indicating how strongly players care about fairness. Note that the case we considered
in class corresponds to ß1 = B2 = 0.
Expert Solution
![](/static/compass_v2/shared-icons/check-mark.png)
This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
This is a popular solution!
Trending now
This is a popular solution!
Step by step
Solved in 3 steps with 5 images
![Blurred answer](/static/compass_v2/solution-images/blurred-answer.jpg)
Knowledge Booster
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.Recommended textbooks for you
![Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337106665/9781337106665_smallCoverImage.gif)
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an…](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781305506381/9781305506381_smallCoverImage.gif)
Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an…
Economics
ISBN:
9781305506381
Author:
James R. McGuigan, R. Charles Moyer, Frederick H.deB. Harris
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337106665/9781337106665_smallCoverImage.gif)
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an…](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781305506381/9781305506381_smallCoverImage.gif)
Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an…
Economics
ISBN:
9781305506381
Author:
James R. McGuigan, R. Charles Moyer, Frederick H.deB. Harris
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
![Exploring Economics](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781544336329/9781544336329_smallCoverImage.jpg)
Exploring Economics
Economics
ISBN:
9781544336329
Author:
Robert L. Sexton
Publisher:
SAGE Publications, Inc
![Microeconomics: Principles & Policy](https://www.bartleby.com/isbn_cover_images/9781337794992/9781337794992_smallCoverImage.jpg)
Microeconomics: Principles & Policy
Economics
ISBN:
9781337794992
Author:
William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. Solow
Publisher:
Cengage Learning