2. Competitive equilibrium in the Edgeworth economy (25 points total) You are the benevo- lent dictator of Sbarroland, an Edgeworth economy of two people-Alessandra and Bruno-and two goods-pizzas (x) and breadsticks (y). The economy has a total of 20 pizzas and a total of 16 breadsticks. The initial endowment is as follows. Alessandra was born owning 4 pizzas, and she was born owning 13 breadsticks. Bruno was born owning the other 16 pizzas and 3 breadsticks. In Edgeworth-style notation, the initial endowment is therefore (4,13,16,3). Unless you use your dictator powers to prevent them from doing so, Alessandra and Bruno will be able to engage whatever mutually-agreeable trades with each other that they like. Alessandra proposes that the two people trade according to a specific pair of prices, where px is the dollar price of a pizza, and py is the dollar price of a breadstick. Given the specific prices that Alessandra has proposed, Bruno calculates that he could afford to turn his initial endowment of 16 pizzas and 3 breadsticks into a final allocation of 14 pizzas and 9 breadsticks. Given that Bruno has done his calculations correctly, what specific numbers might Alessandra have proposed for px and py? (Note: There are multiple possible correct answers.) Explain. 2 The Edgeworth box shown here represents Sbarroland. It is drawn perfectly to scale (each grid square is 1x1). The picture depicts two of Alessandra's indifference curves (labeled A1 and A2) and two of Bruno's indifference curves (labeled B1 and B2). The picture also depicts two perfectly straight dashed lines, which are not indifference curves at all, but rather are provided as tools to help you answer the questions below. The black dots are also provided as helpful tools: Each dot has whole-number coordinates and sits at a location where two or more curves/lines meet. Breadsticks → 82 B1 Pizzas 10 A1 A2 OB Consider the pair of prices that you named in your answer to part 2a above. Could these prices be part of a competitive equilibrium, given what we know about Alessandra and Bruno? Explain. Now consider the allocation z = (14,8,6,8). Could z be the final allocation for a competitive equilibrium? Explain. (d) Does the initial endowment represent a Pareto efficient allocation? Explain. 3 (e) Is z a Pareto efficient allocation? Explain. (f) True or false: The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics indicates that a government intervention may be needed in order to ensure that Alessandra and Bruno don't end up consuming their precise initial endowments. Explain.

ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
14th Edition
ISBN:9780190931919
Author:NEWNAN
Publisher:NEWNAN
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Question
100%
2. Competitive equilibrium in the Edgeworth economy (25 points total) You are the benevo-
lent dictator of Sbarroland, an Edgeworth economy of two people-Alessandra and
Bruno-and two goods-pizzas (x) and breadsticks (y). The economy has a total of
20 pizzas and a total of 16 breadsticks.
The initial endowment is as follows. Alessandra was born owning 4 pizzas, and
she was born owning 13 breadsticks. Bruno was born owning the other 16 pizzas
and 3 breadsticks. In Edgeworth-style notation, the initial endowment is therefore
(4,13,16,3). Unless you use your dictator powers to prevent them from doing so,
Alessandra and Bruno will be able to engage whatever mutually-agreeable trades
with each other that they like.
Alessandra proposes that the two people trade according to a specific pair of prices,
where px is the dollar price of a pizza, and py is the dollar price of a breadstick.
Given the specific prices that Alessandra has proposed, Bruno calculates that he
could afford to turn his initial endowment of 16 pizzas and 3 breadsticks into a final
allocation of 14 pizzas and 9 breadsticks.
Given that Bruno has done his calculations correctly, what specific numbers
might Alessandra have proposed for px and py? (Note: There are multiple
possible correct answers.) Explain.
2
The Edgeworth box shown here represents Sbarroland. It is drawn perfectly to scale (each
grid square is 1x1). The picture depicts two of Alessandra's indifference curves (labeled A1
and A2) and two of Bruno's indifference curves (labeled B1 and B2). The picture also depicts
two perfectly straight dashed lines, which are not indifference curves at all, but rather are
provided as tools to help you answer the questions below. The black dots are also provided
as helpful tools: Each dot has whole-number coordinates and sits at a location where two or
more curves/lines meet.
Breadsticks →
82
B1
Pizzas
10
A1
A2
OB
Consider the pair of prices that you named in your answer to part 2a above.
Could these prices be part of a competitive equilibrium, given what we know
about Alessandra and Bruno? Explain.
Now consider the allocation z = (14,8,6,8). Could z be the final allocation for a
competitive equilibrium? Explain.
(d) Does the initial endowment represent a Pareto efficient allocation? Explain.
3
(e) Is z a Pareto efficient allocation? Explain.
(f) True or false: The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics indicates that a
government intervention may be needed in order to ensure that Alessandra and Bruno
don't end up consuming their precise initial endowments. Explain.
Transcribed Image Text:2. Competitive equilibrium in the Edgeworth economy (25 points total) You are the benevo- lent dictator of Sbarroland, an Edgeworth economy of two people-Alessandra and Bruno-and two goods-pizzas (x) and breadsticks (y). The economy has a total of 20 pizzas and a total of 16 breadsticks. The initial endowment is as follows. Alessandra was born owning 4 pizzas, and she was born owning 13 breadsticks. Bruno was born owning the other 16 pizzas and 3 breadsticks. In Edgeworth-style notation, the initial endowment is therefore (4,13,16,3). Unless you use your dictator powers to prevent them from doing so, Alessandra and Bruno will be able to engage whatever mutually-agreeable trades with each other that they like. Alessandra proposes that the two people trade according to a specific pair of prices, where px is the dollar price of a pizza, and py is the dollar price of a breadstick. Given the specific prices that Alessandra has proposed, Bruno calculates that he could afford to turn his initial endowment of 16 pizzas and 3 breadsticks into a final allocation of 14 pizzas and 9 breadsticks. Given that Bruno has done his calculations correctly, what specific numbers might Alessandra have proposed for px and py? (Note: There are multiple possible correct answers.) Explain. 2 The Edgeworth box shown here represents Sbarroland. It is drawn perfectly to scale (each grid square is 1x1). The picture depicts two of Alessandra's indifference curves (labeled A1 and A2) and two of Bruno's indifference curves (labeled B1 and B2). The picture also depicts two perfectly straight dashed lines, which are not indifference curves at all, but rather are provided as tools to help you answer the questions below. The black dots are also provided as helpful tools: Each dot has whole-number coordinates and sits at a location where two or more curves/lines meet. Breadsticks → 82 B1 Pizzas 10 A1 A2 OB Consider the pair of prices that you named in your answer to part 2a above. Could these prices be part of a competitive equilibrium, given what we know about Alessandra and Bruno? Explain. Now consider the allocation z = (14,8,6,8). Could z be the final allocation for a competitive equilibrium? Explain. (d) Does the initial endowment represent a Pareto efficient allocation? Explain. 3 (e) Is z a Pareto efficient allocation? Explain. (f) True or false: The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics indicates that a government intervention may be needed in order to ensure that Alessandra and Bruno don't end up consuming their precise initial endowments. Explain.
Expert Solution
steps

Step by step

Solved in 2 steps

Blurred answer
Similar questions
  • SEE MORE QUESTIONS
Recommended textbooks for you
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
Economics
ISBN:
9780190931919
Author:
NEWNAN
Publisher:
Oxford University Press
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education