Lectures_on_Urban_Economics_----_(2_Analyzing_Urban_Spatial_Structure)

pdf

School

University of Toronto *

*We aren’t endorsed by this school

Course

ECO333

Subject

Geography

Date

Oct 30, 2023

Type

pdf

Pages

28

Uploaded by ChefJellyfishMaster1979

Report
2 Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 2.1 Introduction Looking out the airplane window, an airline passenger landing in New York or Chicago would see the features of urban spatial structure rep- resented in a particularly dramatic fashion. In both of those cities, the urban center has a striking concentration of tall buildings, with build- ing heights gradually falling as distance from the center increases. The tallest buildings in both cities are office buildings and other commercial structures, but the central areas also contain many tall residential build- ings. Like the heights of the office buildings, the heights of these resi- dential structures decrease moving away from the center, dropping to three and two stories as distance increases. Single-story houses become common in the distant suburbs. Although it is less obvious from the airplane, an equally important spatial feature of cities involves the sizes of individual dwellings (apart- ments and houses). The dwellings within the tall residential buildings near the city center tend to be relatively small in terms of square footage, while suburban houses are much more spacious. Thus, although building heights fall moving away from the center, dwelling sizes increase. In walking around downtown residential neighborhoods in Chicago or New York, the traveler would notice another difference not clearly visible from the airplane. Relative to her suburban neighborhood at home, there would be many more people on the streets in these down- town neighborhoods, walking to restaurants, running errands, or heading to their workplaces. This difference is due to the high popula- tion density that prevails in central-city residential areas, which is also reflected in activities on the street. Population density falls moving away from the city center, reaching a much lower level in the suburbs. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
24 Chapter 2 Other important regularities of urban spatial structure aren’t visible at all from an airplane or from the street. These features involve real- estate prices, and they require experience in real-estate transactions, or familiarity with urban data, to grasp. First, whereas vacant lots usually can be purchased for reasonable prices in the suburbs, vacant land near the city center (when it is available) is dramatically more expensive per acre. The same regularity applies to the price of housing floor space: the rental or purchase price per square foot of housing is much higher near the city center than in the suburbs. Consumers aren’t used to thinking about prices on a per square foot basis (focusing instead on the monthly rent or selling price for a dwelling), but any real-estate agent knows that residential prices per square foot fall moving away from the city center. Other regularities involve differences across cities rather than center- suburban differences within a single city. To appreciate these differ- ences, suppose that our traveler is from Omaha, Nebraska. When her plane lands there on her return trip, she will notice that buildings in central Omaha, though taller than those in Omaha’s suburbs, are much shorter than those in the big city she just visited. In addition, if the traveler had access to price data, she would see that a vacant lot in the center of Omaha would be cheaper than one in the center of New York. Economists have formulated a mathematical model of cities that attempts to capture all these regularities of urban spatial structure. This chapter develops and explains the model. But it does so without relying on mathematics, instead using an accessible diagrammatic approach. As will be seen, the urban model successfully predicts the regularities described above. Since the model thus gives an accurate picture of cities, it can be used reliably for predictive purposes in a policy context. For example, the model can predict how a city’s spatial structure would change if the gasoline tax were raised substantially, thereby raising the cost of driving. It can also be used to analyze how a variety of other policies would affect a city’s spatial structure. The model presented in this chapter originated in the works of William Alonso (1964), Richard Muth (1969), and Edwin Mills (1967). Systematic derivation of the model’s predictions was first done by William Wheaton (1974) and later elaborated by Jan Brueckner (1987). 1 1. For a comprehensive treatment of the economics of urban land use, see Fujita 1989. For a more recent book-length treatment, see Papageorgiou and Pines 1998. Glaeser 2008 also contains a chapter on this topic. For a useful overview paper, see Anas, Arnott, and Small 1998. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 25 The presentation in this chapter is basically a nonmathematical version of Brueckner’s approach. 2.2 Basic Assumptions As is true of all economic models, the urban model is based on strategi- cally chosen simplifications, which facilitate a simple analysis. These simplifications are chosen to capture the essential features of cities, leaving out details that may be less important. Once the model is ana- lyzed and its predictions are derived, greater realism can be added, often with little effect on the main conclusions. The first assumption is that all the city’s jobs are in the center, in an area called the “central business district” (CBD). In reality, many job sites are outside city centers, scattered in various locations or else con- centrated in remote employment subcenters. Thus, although job decen- tralization (the movement of jobs out of the CBD) is a hallmark of modern cities, this process is initially ignored in developing the model. It therefore applies best to cities of the early to mid twentieth century, in which jobs were more centralized than they are now. However, once the model has been analyzed, it can be realistically modified to include the formation of employment subcenters. As will be seen, many of its lessons are unaffected. Since the goal is to analyze residential (as opposed to business) land use, the CBD is collapsed to a single point at the city center, so that it takes up no space. The model could easily be modified to allow the CBD to have a positive land area, in which case the nature of land use within the business area would become a focus in addition to residen- tial land use outside the CBD. The second major assumption is that the city has a dense network of radial roads. With such a network, a resident living some distance from the CBD can travel to work in a radial direction, straight into the center, as illustrated in figure 2.1. In reality, cities are criss-crossed by freeways, which are often used in combination with surface streets to access the CBD, thus leading to non-radial automobile commute paths for many residents. As will be seen below, freeways can be added to the model without changing its essential lessons. The third major assumption is that the city contains identical house- holds. Each household has the same preferences over consumption goods, and each earns the same income from work at the CBD. For simplicity, household size is normalized to one, so that the city consists Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
26 Chapter 2 entirely of single-person households. The identical-household assump- tion is relaxed below by allowing the city to have two different income groups: rich and poor. The fourth major assumption is that the city’s residents consume only two goods: housing and a composite good that consists of every- thing other than housing. Since the model is about cities, it naturally focuses on housing. Simplicity requires that all other consumption be lumped together into a single composite commodity, which will be called “bread.” 2.3 Commuting Cost Let x denote radial distance from a consumer’s residence to the CBD. The cost of commuting to work at the CBD is higher the larger is x , and this cost generally has two components. The first is a “money” (or “out-of-pocket”) cost. For an automobile user, the money cost consists of the cost of gasoline and insurance as well as depreciation on the automobile. For a public-transit user, the money cost is simply the transit fare. The second component of commuting cost is time cost, which captures the “opportunity cost” of the time spent commuting— time that is mostly unavailable for other productive or enjoyable activities. Because a proper consideration of time cost makes the analysis more complicated, this component of commuting cost is ignored in developing the basic model. However, time cost is needed in analyzing a city that contains different income groups, so it will be re-introduced below. Residence Residence CBD Figure 2.1 Radial commuting. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 27 The parameter t represents the per-mile cost of commuting. For a resident living x miles from the CBD, total commuting cost per period is then tx , or commuting cost per mile times distance. For an automo- bile commuter, t would be computed as follows: Suppose that operat- ing the automobile costs $0.45 per mile, a number close to the value allowed by the Internal Revenue Service in deducting expenses for business use of an auto. Then, a one-way trip to the CBD from a residence at distance x costs 0.45 x , and a round trip costs 0.90 x . A resident working 50 weeks per year will make 250 round trips to the CBD. Multiplying the previous expression by this number yields (250)0.90 x = 225 x as the commuting cost per year from distance x . Thus, under these assumptions t would equal 225. 2 The fact that the same commuting-cost parameter ( t ) applies to all residents reflects another implicit assumption of the model: all resi- dents use the same transport mode to get to work. Urban models with competing transport modes (and thus different possible mode choices) have been developed, but they involve additional complexity. Let the income earned per period at the CBD by each resident be denoted by y . Then disposable income, net of commuting cost, for a resident living at distance x is equal to y tx. This expression shows that disposable income decreases as x increases, a consequence of a longer and more costly commute. This fact is crucial in generating the model’s predictions about urban spatial structure. 2.4 Consumer Analysis As was mentioned earlier, city residents consume two goods: housing and “bread.” Bread consumption is denoted by c , and since the price per unit is normalized to $1, c gives dollars spent on bread (all goods other than housing). Housing consumption is denoted by q , but the physical units corresponding to q must be chosen. The problem is that housing is a complicated good, with a variety of characteristics that consumers value. The characteristics of housing include square footage of floor space in the dwelling, yard size, construction quality, age, and amenities (views, for example). Although a dwelling is then best 2. Note that the model focuses entirely on commuting cost, ignoring the cost of trips carried out for other purposes (such as shopping). These trips might be viewed as occur- ring close to home at a cost that is negligible relative to the cost of commuting. Alterna- tively, the consumer could be assumed to shop on the way home from work at no extra cost, a behavior that appears to be common. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
28 Chapter 2 described by a vector of characteristics, the model requires that con- sumption be measured by a single number. The natural choice is square footage, the feature that consumers probably care about most. Thus, q represents the square feet of floor space in a dwelling. With this measurement choice, the price per unit of housing is then the price per square foot of floor space, denoted by p . For simplicity, the model assumes that everyone in the city is a renter, so that p is the rental price per square foot. 3 Note that “rent,” or the rental payment per period, is different from p . It equals pq , or price per square foot times housing consumption in square feet. In digesting the model, it is important to grasp this distinction between the rental price per square foot and the more common notion of rent, which is a total payment. The consumer’s budget constraint, which equates expenditures on bread and housing to disposable income net of commuting cost, is c + pq = y tx . The budget constraint says that expenditure on bread (which equals c given bread’s unitary price) plus expenditure on housing (“rent,” or pq ) equals disposable income. The consumer’s utility function, which gives the satisfaction from consuming a particular ( c, q ) bundle, is given by u ( c, q ). As usual, the consumer chooses c and q to maximize utility subject to the budget constraint. The optimal consumption bundle lies at a point of tangency between an indifference curve and the budget line, as will be shown below. As was explained in section 2.1, one of the regularities of urban spatial structure is that the price per square foot of housing floor space declines as distance to the CBD increases. In other words, p falls as x increases. The first step in the analysis is to show that the model indeed predicts this regularity. The demonstration makes use of a simple intui- tive argument, which is then reinforced by a diagrammatic analysis. The argument relies on a fundamental condition for consumer loca- tional equilibrium. This equilibrium condition says that consumers must be equally well off at all locations, achieving the same utility regardless of where they live in the city . If this condition did not hold, then consum- ers in a low-utility area could gain by moving into a high-utility area. This incentive to move means that a locational equilibrium has not been attained. The incentive is absent, implying that equilibrium has 3. The model could equally well have everyone be a homeowner, with the appropriate relabeling. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 29 been reached, only when consumer utility—that is, the value taken by the utility function u ( c, q )—is the same everywhere. Utilities can be spatially uniform only if the price per unit of housing floor space falls as distance increases. Since higher commuting costs mean that disposable income falls as x increases, some offsetting benefit must be present to keep utility from falling. The offsetting benefit is a lower price per square foot of housing at greater distances. Then, even though consumers living far from the center have less money to spend (after paying high commuting costs) than those closer to the CBD, their money goes farther given a lower p , allowing them to be just as well off as people living closer in. The lower p thus compensates for the disadvantage of higher commuting costs at distant locations. This explanation makes it clear that the lower p at distant suburban locations serves as a compensating differential that reconciles suburban residents to their long and costly commutes. Compensating differen- tials also arise in many other economic contexts. For example, danger- ous or unpleasant jobs must pay higher wages than more appealing jobs with similar skill requirements. Otherwise, no one would do the undesirable work. Like the lower suburban p , the higher wage recon- ciles people to accepting a disadvantageous situation. 4 While the compensating-differential perspective is the best way to think about spatial variation in p , another view that may seem easier to understand focuses on “demand.” One might argue that the “demand” for suburban locations is lower than the demand for central locations given their high commuting cost. Lower demand then depresses the price of housing at locations far from the CBD, causing p to decline as x increases. The inverse relationship between p and x can also be derived using an indifference-curve diagram, as in figure 2.2. The vertical axis repre- sents bread consumption ( c ) and the horizontal axis housing consump- tion ( q ). The steep budget line pertains to a consumer living at a central-city location, close to the CBD, with x = x 0 . The c intercept of the consumer’s budget line equals disposable income, which is y tx 0 for this individual. The slope of the budget line, on the other hand, equals the negative of the price per square foot of housing. Thus, the 4. Because the price of bread is assumed to be the same in all locations (normalized to $1 per unit), it cannot play a compensating role, as p can. Concretely, this assumption means that the prices of groceries and other non-housing goods are the same at all loca- tions in the city. Although this requirement may not be fully realistic, it is likely to hold approximately. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
30 Chapter 2 slope of the budget line for the central-city consumer equals p 0 , where p 0 is the price per square foot prevailing at x = x 0 . Given this budget line, the consumer maximizes utility, reaching a tangency point between an indifference curve and the budget line. In the figure, this tangency point is ( q 0 , c 0 ). Thus, this central-city resident consumes c 0 worth of bread and q 0 square feet of housing. Now consider a consumer living at a suburban location, with x = x 1 > x 0 . This consumer has disposable income of y tx 1 , less than that of the central-city consumer. As a result, the consumer’s budget line has a smaller intercept than the central-city budget line, as can be seen in the figure. The main question concerns the price per square foot of housing at this suburban location, denoted by p 1 . What magnitude must this price have in order to ensure that the suburban consumer is just as well off as the central-city consumer? The answer is that p 1 must lead to a budget line that allows the suburban consumer to reach the same indifference curve as her central-city counterpart. For this outcome to be possible, the suburban budget line, with its lower intercept, must be flatter than the central-city line. When the budget line is flatter by just the right degree, the utility-maximizing point will lie on the indif- ference curve reached by the central-city consumer, as seen in the figure. But since the slope of the budget line equals the negative of the housing price, it follows that a flatter budget line (with a negative slope closer to zero) must have a lower price. Therefore, the suburban price p 1 must Slope = – p 0 Slope = – p 1 y tx 1 y tx 0 c q ( q 0 , c 0 ) ( q 1 , c 1 ) Figure 2.2 Consumer choice. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 31 be lower than the central-city price p 0 , so that p 1 < p 0 . Figure 2.2 thus establishes that the price per square foot of housing p must fall as dis- tance x to the CBD increases, confirming the previous intuitive argument. Figure 2.2 contains additional important information about con- sumer choices. The suburban consumption bundle ( q 1 , c 1 ), which is the point of tangency between the suburban budget line and the indif- ference curve, can be compared with the central-city bundle ( q 0 , c 0 ). From the figure, this comparison shows that the suburban resident consumes more square feet of housing and less bread than the central-city resident . Therefore, suburban dwellings are larger than central-city dwellings, so that dwelling size q rises as distance from the CBD increases . This substitution in favor of housing and away from bread is the con- sumer’s response to the decline in the relative price of housing as x increases. 5 Recall from above that this pattern was one of the main regularities of urban spatial structure, and the figure shows that the model predicts it. The difference in bread consumption indicates an additional pattern: while occupying a small dwelling, the central-city resident consumes a lot of bread. Concretely, this resident has a nice car, beautiful furni- ture, and gourmet food in the refrigerator, and takes expensive vaca- tions. The suburban resident’s consumption, in contrast, is skewed toward housing consumption, with less emphasis on bread. Given that the city only has one income group, this prediction may be not very realistic, and it doesn’t survive the generalization of the model to include multiple income groups. But the (realistic) prediction regarding dwelling-size variation with distance is robust to this generalization, as will be seen below. So far, the model’s two main predictions are that the price per square foot of housing falls, and that size of dwellings rises, as distance to the CBD increases. These outcomes can be represented symbolically as follows: p as x , q as x . With these important conclusions established, several aspects of the preceding analysis deserve more discussion. The consumer has been portrayed as choosing her dwelling size on the basis of the prevailing price per square foot at a given location. Although most consumers 5. Since utility is fixed, the increase in q in response to the lower housing price represents the substitution effect of the price change (the income effect is not present). Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
32 Chapter 2 aren’t used to thinking about the price per square foot of housing (focusing instead on total rent), the model assumes that they implicitly recognize the existence of such a price in making decisions. For example, a small apartment with a high rent would be viewed as expensive by a consumer, but the individual would be implicitly reacting to the apartment’s high rental price per square foot. Indeed, commercial space is always rented in this fashion, with a landlord quoting a rent per square foot and the tenant choosing a quantity of space. But one might then argue that residential tenants aren’t offered such a quantity choice (they can’t, after all, adjust the square footage of an apartment), making the model’s portrayal of the choice of dwelling size seem unrealistic. The response is that the consumer’s quantity preferences are ultimately reflected in the existing housing stock. In other words, the size of apartments built in a particular location is exactly the one that consumers prefer, given the prevailing price per square foot. Two additional conclusions can be drawn from consumer side of the model. The first concerns the nature of the curve relating the housing price p to distance. The curve is convex, as in figure 2.3, with the price falling at a decreasing rate as x increases. This conclusion follows from mathematical analysis, which shows that the slope of the housing-price curve is given by the following equation: $ p x Figure 2.3 Housing-price curve. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 33 p x = t q . Therefore, the slope at any location is equal to the negative of commut- ing cost per mile divided by the dwelling size at that location. The convexity in figure 2.3 follows because q increases with x , so that the t / q ratio becomes less negative (and the curve flatter) as distance increases. The intuitive explanation is that at a suburban location where dwellings are large a small decline in the price per square foot is suf- ficient to generate enough housing-cost savings to compensate for an extra mile’s commute. But at a central-city location, where dwellings are small, a larger decline in the price per square foot is needed to generate the required savings. A second conclusion concerns the spatial behavior of total rent, pq . The question is how the total rent for a small central-city dwelling compares to the total rent for a larger suburban house. The answer is that the comparison is ambiguous. Since p falls with x while q increases, the product pq could either rise or fall with x , with the pattern depend- ing on the shape of the consumer’s indifference curve in figure 2.2. The implication is that the total rent for the suburban house could be either larger or smaller than the rent for the central-city apartment, a conclu- sion that appears realistic. A large body of empirical work confirms the model’s prediction of a link between price per square foot of housing and job accessibility. The approach uses a “hedonic price” regression (explained further in chapter 6) that relates the value of a dwelling to its size and other characteristics, one of which is distance from the city’s employment center. These regressions usually show a negative distance effect. Thus, with dwelling size held constant, value falls as distance rises, which in turn implies a decline in value (and thus rent) per square foot. 6 2.5 Analysis of Housing Production Now that the consumer’s choice of dwelling size has been analyzed, the next step is to ask what the buildings containing those dwellings look like. To address this question, the focus shifts to the activities of housing developers, who build structures and rent the space to consumers. 7 6. For an example of such a study, see Coulson 1991. 7. In reality, developers sell buildings to landlords, who then rent space to consumers, but this intervening agent is ignored. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
34 Chapter 2 In reality, developers produce housing floor space using a variety of inputs, including land, building materials, labor, and machinery. As in the consumer analysis, simplicity requires narrowing down the list of choice variables. Thus, the model assumes that floor space is produced with land and building materials alone, ignoring the role of labor and machinery. In one sense, this view isn’t unreasonable, given that the land and materials inputs are present over the entire life of a building, while construction workers and machines (though crucial) are present only for a relatively short time at the outset. The production function for housing floor space is written as Q = H ( N , l ), where Q is the floor space contained in a building, N is the amount of building materials (measured in some fashion), l is the land input, and H is the production function. An engineer or an architect would point out that building materials are certainly not a homoge- neous category (they include steel, wood, concrete, glass, and so on), but these distinctions are ignored for simplicity in measuring the mate- rial input. For convenience, building materials will sometimes be referred to as the “capital” input into housing production. Several properties of the production function deserve note. The first is the diminishing marginal product of capital. This property means that, with the land input held fixed, extra doses of building materials lead to smaller and smaller increases in floor space. This property makes sense when it is recognized that increasing N while holding l fixed makes the building taller, as can be seen in figure 2.4. Diminishing returns arise because, as the building gets taller, addi- Additional N N Figure 2.4 Making a building taller. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 35 tional doses of building materials are increasingly consumed in uses that do not directly yield extra floor space. These uses include a stron- ger foundation, thicker beams, and more space devoted to elevators and stairways. The second property of interest is the degree of returns to scale in housing production. In the discussion of scale economies in chapter 1, only a single input was present, and the presence of scale economies could be inferred by simply looking at the graph of the production function. Although the graph is more complicated with two inputs, economies of scale are present in housing production if doubling both the capital and land inputs leads to more than a doubling of floor space. This doubling of inputs is evident in figure 2.5, where it leads, in effect, to the construction of a second identical building adjoining the original one. The question is whether this building has more than twice the floor space of the original building. It might appear that the answer is No, with floor space instead exactly doubling. But that conclusion ignores what might be a slight gain from the fact that the exterior wall of the original building is now an interior wall, which could be thinner. Since this gain is probably small, it is safe to say that housing production exhibits approximate “constant returns to scale,” with scale economies not present in any important way. Figures 2.4 and 2.5 reflect an underlying assumption that has not been made explicit so far. The assumption is that the building com- pletely covers the land area l , leaving no yard or open space around it. This view is logical since consumers have been portrayed as only valuing floor space, so that any land devoted to open space would be wasted. But the assumption is clearly unrealistic, at least for suburban N N Figure 2.5 Constant returns to scale. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
36 Chapter 2 areas where yard space is plentiful. Strictly speaking, the model can be viewed as pertaining to a place, such as Manhattan or central Paris, where there are few yards. The model can, however, be generalized to allow yard space to be valued by consumers and provided by develop- ers, but the resulting framework is more complex. The housing developer will choose the capital and land inputs for his building to maximize profit, leading to a structure of a particular height. Implicitly, the developer also sets the size of the dwellings within the structure, but this decision simply responds to consumer choices. In other words, the floor space in a building is divided up into dwellings of the size that consumers want at that particular location. This division is illustrated in figure 2.6. The revenue earned by the developer is equal to pH ( N , l ), the price per square foot p times the square footage in the building. Input costs consist of the cost of building materials and the cost of land. To match the rental orientation of the model, both inputs are viewed as being rented rather than purchased. Thus, the developer leases land from its owner rather than purchasing it outright, an arrangement that is occa- sionally seen (in China, for example, all land is owned by the govern- ment and is leased to developers). Land rent per acre is thus the relevant input price, and it is denoted by r . The rental rate per unit of building materials is equal to i , 8 and this price is assumed to be independent of where the structure is built. In other words, building materials are N Figure 2.6 Division of a building into dwellings. 8. Note that i could instead be viewed as the annualized cost of materials that are pur- chased rather than rented. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 37 delivered to any construction site, regardless of its location in the city, at a common price per unit. Combining all this information, the devel- oper’s production cost is equal to iN + rl. Although i doesn’t vary with location, spatial variation in land rent r is necessary to make developers willing to produce housing throughout the city. The reason is that locations far from the CBD are disadvantageous for development since the price p received by the developer per square foot of floor space is low. In contrast, locations close to the CBD are favorable since the developer can charge a high price per square foot there for his output. In order for developers to be willing to build housing in all locations, the profit from doing so must be the same everywhere. But with close-in locations offering higher revenue per square foot than suburban loca- tions, profits will not be uniform unless a compensating differential exists on the cost side. With the capital cost fixed, this compensating differential must come from spatial variation in land rent r . In particu- lar, land rent must be lower in the suburbs than at central locations. With r falling as x increases, the revenue disadvantage of the suburbs is offset, and the profits from housing development remain constant over space. Because land rent must do all the work in equalizing profits, given that i is fixed, r must fall with distance much faster than p itself, declining at a greater percentage rate. Therefore, the gap between central-city values and suburban values is wider for r than for p . As in the consumer analysis, this compensating differential can be viewed as a demand-based phenomenon. Developers will compete vigorously for land in central locations because floor space built there commands a high price. This competition bids up land rents near the CBD. Conversely, developers’ lower demand for suburban land, a con- sequence of the low housing revenue it offers, leads to a lower land rent. Since competition for land among developers will bid up rent until profit is exhausted, the uniform profit achieved through compen- sating land-rent differentials is in fact a zero profit level (corresponding to “normal” economic profit). The model thus predicts another one of the regularities of urban spatial structure: declining land rent (and thus land value) as distance to the CBD increases. 9 This pattern, in turn, generates another regularity 9. A number of empirical studies have confirmed the negative association between land values and distance (see, for example, McMillen 1996). However, a greater number of studies have documented the link between housing prices and distance to the CBD. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
38 Chapter 2 related to building heights. With the price of capital fixed and land rent rising moving toward the CBD, the land input becomes more expensive relative to the capital input as distance x declines. Producers generally shift their input mix in response to changes in relative input prices, and housing developers are no exception. In particular, as land becomes more expensive compared to capital, developers econo- mize on the land input and use more capital in the production of floor space. But in making this substitution, the developer is building a taller structure (recall figure 2.4). Thus, as land becomes relatively more expensive moving toward the CBD, developers respond by construct- ing taller buildings. Conversely, as land gets cheaper moving toward the suburbs, developers use it more lavishly, constructing shorter build- ings. Overall, then, building height decreases as distance to the CBD increases. This pattern can be seen from a diagram showing cost minimization on the part of the housing developer. In figure 2.7, the capital input is on the vertical axis and the land input is on horizontal axis. The isoquant shows all the capital-land combinations capable of producing a particular amount floor space, say 150,000 square feet. Consider first the choice problem of a developer at a central-city location where x = x 0 and r = r 0 . The iso-cost lines at this central location have slope r 0 / i , and they are relatively steep since r 0 is high. To produce 150,000 N ( 0 , N 0 ) ( 1 , N 1 ) Q = 150,000 square feet Slope = – r 1 i Slope = – r 0 i Figure 2.7 Cost minimization by housing developer. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 39 square feet of floor space as cheaply as possible, the developer finds the input bundle on the isoquant lying on the lowest possible iso-cost line. This bundle, denoted by ( l 0 , N 0 ), lies at a point of tangency, as can be seen in the figure. In contrast, a developer building 150,000 square feet at a suburban location, where x = x l > x 0 and r = r 1 < r 0 , faces flatter iso-cost lines. His cost-minimizing input bundle is ( l 1 , N 1 ), which has less capital and more land than the central-city bundle. Instead of building a high-rise structure like the one at x 0 , this developer builds a garden-apartment complex. Building heights in the two developments are reflected in the amount of capital per acre of land, given by the ratios N 0 / l 0 and N 1 / l 1 . These ratios are equal to the slopes of the rays shown in the figure that connect the input bundles to the origin. With the central-city ray steeper, it follows that the building at x 0 is taller than the building at x 1 . Thus, building height falls moving away from the CBD. 10 The two main predictions from the producer analysis are that land rent per acre and building height both fall as distance to the CBD increases. Symbolically, r as x , building height as x . 2.6 Population Density A final intracity regularity is the decline of population density with distance to the CBD, which the model also generates. Population density, denoted by D , is equal to people per acre. But since dwellings contain a single person, D is just dwellings per acre. Figure 2.8 illus- trates the difference between dwellings per acre in the central city and the suburbs. The central-city location has a tall building (with high capital per acre) that is divided into small dwellings, while the subur- ban location has a short building divided into large dwellings. From the figure, dwellings per acre is clearly higher at the central-city loca- tion than in the suburbs. In other words, since suburban buildings have less floor space per acre of land and contain larger dwellings than central-city buildings, the suburbs have fewer dwellings per acre than the central city. Thus, D falls moving away from the CBD. Symbolically, D as x . 10. This prediction is confirmed by McMillen 2006 and by other studies. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
40 Chapter 2 Most empirical testing of the urban model has focused on testing this prediction about the spatial behavior of population density. Dozens of empirical studies have investigated the relationship between density and distance to the CBD for individual cities all over the world. 11 These studies rely on the fact that cities are divided into small spatial zones for census purposes, with the population of the zones tabulated. Once the land area of each zone has been estimated, the zone’s popula- tion density can be computed by dividing the population by its area. In addition, the distance from the zone to the CBD can be mea- sured. The result is a point scatter in density-distance space like that shown in figure 2.9. The empirical researcher then runs a regression, which generates a curve passing through the point scatter, as shown in the figure. 12 The estimated density curves for the world’s cities are almost always downward sloping, confirming the prediction of the model. The entire set of intra-city predictions is summarized in figure 2.10, which shows the logical linkages involved in the predictions. The solid boxes in the figure contain the two fundamental equilibrium conditions in the model: spatially uniform consumer utility and spatially uniform Suburbs (fewer dwellings per acre) Central city (many dwellings per acre) Figure 2.8 Population density. 11. See McDonald 1989 for a survey. 12. A common assumption is that density follows a negative exponential relationship, with D = α e β x . Taking natural logs, this relationship reduces to log D = θ β x, showing a linear relationship between log D and x . With density measured in logs, the regression curve in figure 2.9 is then replaced by a straight line. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 41 (zero) developer profit. The dashed box in the figure contains the crucial real-world fact that drives the entire model: the increase in com- muting cost as distance increases. The logical arrows show how this real-world fact and the two equilibrium conditions combine to generate the various predictions. The increase in commuting cost with distance and the requirement of uniform utility imply that p falls with x , which in turn implies that q rises with x . The zero-profit requirement and the decline in p with x imply that r falls with x . The decline in r then implies that building height falls with x . Finally, the rise in q and decline in building height as x increases imply that D falls with x . x Population density Regression line Figure 2.9 Population-density regression. Spatially uniform utility Spatially uniform (zero) profit Commuting cost as x Building height as x p as x D as x q as x r as x Figure 2.10 Logical structure of the model. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
42 Chapter 2 2.7 Intercity Predictions As was explained earlier, the model also generates intercity predictions that match observed regularities. For example, the model predicts that large cities will have taller buildings than small cities. To generate these predictions, it is necessary to analyze what might be called the “supply- demand” equilibrium of the city. Basically, the equilibrium requirement is that the city fits its population, or that the “supply” of housing equals the “demand” for it. The size of the land area occupied by a city determines how much housing the city contains. The city’s land area is, in turn, the result of competition between housing developers and farmers for use of the land. Suppose that farmers are willing to pay a rent of r A per acre of land. This agricultural rent will be high when the land is very produc- tive or when the crops grown on it command a high price. Although r A might vary with location, being higher near the delivery points for agricultural output (where transport cost is low), this rent will instead be viewed as constant over space, thus being independent of x . Figure 2.11 shows the graph of r A , which is a horizontal line, along with the downward-sloping urban land-rent curve. Like the housing-price curve in figure 2.3, the land-rent curve is convex, with r decreasing at a decreasing rate as x increases. r A x r $ Housing Farms x Figure 2.11 Determination of city’s edge. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 43 A landowner will rent his land to the bidder who offers most for it. 13 Figure 2.11 shows that the housing developer is the highest bidder at locations inside the intersection point of the r curve and the r A line, while the farmer is the highest bidder at locations outside this intersection. Therefore, housing is built inside the intersection, while the land outside the intersection is in agricultural use. The inter- section point, which is x miles from the CBD, thus represents the edge of the city. For the city to be in supply-demand equilibrium, its fixed population (denoted by L ) must exactly fit in the housing available inside x . The city’s supply-demand equilibrium depends on the four key parameters of the model: population ( L ), agricultural rent ( r A ), com- muting cost ( t ), and income ( y ). 14 By changing a particular parameter and deducing the resulting changes in urban spatial structure, the intercity predictions can be derived. 15 2.7.1 The effects of population and agricultural land rent Consider first the effect of population size. The city is assumed to start in equilibrium, exactly fitting its population L . Then the population size is hypothetically increased—a change that disrupts the equilibrium, since the larger population doesn’t fit in the existing city. The analysis then deduces the changes in urban spatial structure that must occur in order to restore equilibrium, allowing the city to fit the now-larger population. This thought experiment shows how the spatial structure of a par- ticular city would respond to an increase in population. Since the city gets rebuilt in response to the population increase (as will be explained below), the predicted changes must be viewed as occurring over a very long time period. But the results of the thought experiment can be interpreted in a different, more useful way. In particular, the differences between the pre-change and post-change cities can be used to predict the differences between two separate cities, one small and one large, at a given point in time . In other words, the long-run changes in spatial structure that would occur in a single city as its population expands should also be reflected in the differences between two coexisting cities with different population sizes. 13. Landowners are assumed to be “absentee” (that is, living outside the city). Otherwise, rental income would be earned by city residents, which would complicate the model. 14. The cost i of housing capital is another parameter, but its effect isn’t of interest here. 15. Exercise 2.1 involves an analysis of this type for a simplified version of the model. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
44 Chapter 2 Suppose a particular city, which starts in equilibrium, experiences a one-time increase in its population L . The sequence of impacts unfolds as follows: 1. Although the city’s housing stock fit the original population, the stock is now too small, leading to excess demand for housing (a housing shortage). 2. This excess demand leads to an increase in the price per square foot of housing p at all locations in the city. 3. With housing now more expensive, consumers choose smaller dwelling sizes. Thus, q falls at all locations, an adjustment that occurs in the long run as the city is rebuilt. 4. By raising housing revenue per square foot, the higher price p boosts the profits of housing developers. With development now more profit- able, developers compete more vigorously for land, driving up land rent r at all locations. 5. In response to the higher cost of land, developers economize on its use, constructing taller buildings at all locations. This change occurs in the long run as the city is rebuilt. 6. With buildings taller and dwellings smaller at each location, the number of dwellings per acre of land rises, leading to higher popula- tion density D at all locations. 7. With r rising at all locations, the urban land-rent curve shifts up to r 1 , as shown in figure 2.12 (where r 0 is the original rent curve). As a result, the distance x to the edge of the city increases from to x 0 to x 1 . 8. Since population density increases everywhere, and since the city’s land area is now larger, it fi ts a larger population. Thus, the excess demand for housing is eliminated, restoring the supply-demand equilibrium. Since these adjustments can be used to predict differences between cities with small and large populations at a given point in time, the following conclusions emerge. The larger city occupies more land than the smaller city. At a given distance from the center, the larger city has taller buildings, smaller dwellings, a higher housing price per square foot, higher land rent, and higher population density than the small city. These predictions match many of the observed differences between large and small cities in the real world. 16 16. Empirical tests of the predicted effects of L , y , r A , and t on city land areas have been carried out. They are discussed in chapter 4. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 45 Now consider the effect of an increase in agricultural rent r A on the city’s spatial structure, with population held fixed. This thought experiment can be used to predict the differences between two coexist- ing cities, one in a region with a high r A and one in a region with a low r A . The first region might be the state of Illinois, which has highly productive farmland; the second might be the state of Arizona, where much of the land is desert and thus has little or no value in agriculture. An increase in agricultural rent from r A0 to r A1 raises the height of the r A line in figure 2.13. With the urban land-rent curve held fixed at r 0 , the x value at the intersection point decreases from x 0 to x ' . Taken literally, this change means that the existing housing between x 0 and x ' is bulldozed and the land is returned to agricultural use. But after this shrinkage in the housing stock, the city no longer fits its population, which leads to excess demand for housing. This situation is exactly the one encountered under step 1 of the population-driven adjustment process above. As a result, the subsequent steps 2–8 unfold in exactly the same fashion as before. Note that the upward shift in the land-rent curve in step 7 leads some of the land initially bulldozed to be returned to urban use, as can be seen in figure 2.13. But the final value of x , again denoted by x 1 , must be smaller than the initial value x 0 . The reason is r A r 1 r 0 x $ x 1 x 0 Figure 2.12 Effect of a higher L . Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
46 Chapter 2 that the city is now denser (recall step 6), which means that its fixed population fits in a smaller land area. Given these conclusions, a city in a high- r A state (say, Peoria, Illinois) differs from a city with approximately the same population located in a low- r A state (say, Tucson, Arizona), in the following ways: The high- r A city is spatially smaller, and at a given distance from the CBD, it has taller buildings, smaller dwellings, a higher housing price per square foot, higher land rent, and higher population density than the low- r A city. In view of the spread-out, low density nature of desert cities, these predictions seem realistic. 2.7.2 The effects of commuting cost and income Now consider the effect of an increase in the commuting-cost param- eter t . Such an increase could be due to a higher price of gasoline, or to an increase in the gasoline tax. When t increases, the existing spatial pattern of housing prices doesn’t adequately compensate for long sub- urban commutes. As a result, suburban commuters will want to move toward the center to reduce their commuting costs. This movement bids up housing prices near the CBD, and reduces them at suburban locations. As a result, the housing-price curve rotates in a clockwise r A 1 r A 0 r 1 r 0 x $ x 1 x x 0 Figure 2.13 Effect of a higher r A . Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 47 direction. The profit of housing developers then rises near the center and falls in the suburbs, leading to stronger competition for central land and weaker competition for suburban land. Land rents then rise near the center and fall in the suburbs, causing a clockwise rotation in the land-rent curve that mimics the rotation of the housing-price curve. This rotation (seen in figure 2.14) leads to a decline in x from x 0 to x 1 . Thus, with the higher commuting cost causing residents to move inward, the land area of the city shrinks. In response to the land-rent rotation in the figure, building heights rise near the center and fall in the city’s shrunken suburbs. Dwelling sizes fall near the center, so that central population density rises given the increase in building height. However, mathematical analysis shows that the change in q is ambiguous in the suburbs, which makes the change in density ambiguous there as well. As before, these changes can be used to predict the differences between two coexisting cities, one of which has a high t and the other a low t (but whose populations have the same size). Since gasoline taxes are much higher in Europe than in the United States, the first city could be European and the second American. The analysis predicts that the European city is more compact, with a smaller land area than its American counterpart. In the center, it has taller buildings, smaller dwellings, a higher housing price per square foot, a higher land rent, $ r A r 1 r 0 x x 1 x 0 Figure 2.14 Effect of a higher t . Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
48 Chapter 2 and higher population density than the American city. If gasoline taxes were to rise substantially in the United States, then American cities would eventually assume the more compact form of their European counterparts. Finally, consider the effect of an increase in consumer income y . Mathematical analysis shows that these effects are exactly the opposite of the effects of a higher t . The housing-price curve rotates in a coun- terclockwise direction, causing the same kind of rotation in the land- rent curve, seen in figure 2.14. As a result, x rises from x 0 to x 1 , so that the city expands spatially. Building heights decrease near the center and increase in the (expanded) suburbs. Dwelling sizes increase, and population density decreases, near the center, although changes are ambiguous in the suburbs. These changes arise from a consumer’s changing locational incen- tives when income increases. With a higher income, consumers will want larger dwellings and will thus have an incentive to move outward, attracted by the lower price per square foot of housing at greater dis- tances. This desire for outward movement will push p up in the suburbs and reduce it in the center, leading to counterclockwise rotation of the housing-price and land-rent curves. The resulting spatial expansion of the city makes sense since higher incomes will raise the aggregate demand for housing and thus the aggregate derived demand for land. Making intercity comparisons, the analysis predicts that a high- income city will be larger spatially than a low-income city. Near the center, it will have shorter buildings, larger dwellings, a lower housing price per square foot, lower land rent, and lower population density than the low-income city. These intercity predictions have been tested empirically, with a focus on the x predictions. As will be explained in more detail in chapter 4, the empirical studies carry out regression analysis relating a city’s land area to its population, income, commuting cost, and the agricultural rent on the surrounding land, with results that support the theory. 2.7.3 Migration between cities The preceding analysis ignores the possibility of migration between cities, in effect looking at a given city in isolation. To analyze intercity migration, the first step is to note that when L , r A , y , or t increases, the welfare of urban residents (as measured by their common utility level) is affected. When L increases, for example, the resulting increase in the housing price p raises the city’s cost of living, which makes the Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
Analyzing Urban Spatial Structure 49 residents worse off. Conversely, an increase in y makes the urban resi- dents better off. 17 Given these effects, variation in L and y across cities can lead to welfare differences, with residents reaching high utility levels in some cities and low utilities in other cities. But if consumers are able to migrate between cities, such utility differences are unsustainable. Just as in the case of the intracity equilibrium, in which consumer utility was the same at all locations, an intercity migration equilibrium must make consumers equally well off regardless of which city they live in . If this requirement were not met, people would move from low-utility cities to high-utility cities until welfare was equalized. When migration is possible, a high-income city, where consumers would otherwise be better off, must have a larger population than a low-income city. The larger population cancels the welfare gain from the higher income, leading to the same utilities in both cities. Intercity migration is the source of the larger population: residents migrate from the low-income city to the high-income one, and migration stops when the city’s population has grown enough to cancel the advantage of its higher income. Therefore, once intercity migration is allowed, the model predicts a positive correlation between city population and income , a relationship that has been confirmed empirically. 18 Intercity migration requires reconsideration of the intercity predic- tions made in section 2.6. Those predictions pertain to a “closed city,” where migration is impossible and the population is set exogenously. When migration is allowed, the “open city” model is appropriate instead. Section 2.6 analyzed the effect of a higher income on the city’s spatial structure with L held fixed, but a different exercise is needed for an open city. In this case, the higher y is automatically accompanied by a larger L (a consequence of migration). The resulting effect on the city’s spatial structure is then the combination of two separate effects: the effect of a higher y , with L held fixed , plus the additional effect of a higher L . Since each change separately leads to an increase in x , the 17. Although the p curve rotates rather than shifts up when y increases (making the impact on the cost of living ambiguous), mathematical analysis nevertheless shows that a higher income raises consumer welfare, as intuition would predict. Conversely, an increase in commuting cost t makes the city’s residents worse off, as does an increase in r A. 18. Since an increase in either commuting cost or agricultural rent makes a city’s resi- dents worse off, a population decrease would be required to restore the original utility level. Therefore, intercity migration equilibrium requires cities with high t values or high r A values to have small populations. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help
50 Chapter 2 combined change also raises x , so that the city’s land area increases. Therefore, with intercity migration, high-income cities are spatially larger than low-income cities, just as in the closed-city model. The other spatial-structure effects of the simultaneous increase in y and L can be derived mathematically. 19 2.8 Summary This chapter has analyzed urban spatial structure using a diagram- matic version of the standard urban model. The model generates real- istic intracity predictions, which show that the price per square foot of housing, land rent, building heights, and population density fall moving away from the CBD, while dwelling size increases. The model also generates intercity predictions, which show that more populous cities are spatially larger, denser, and more expensive than small cities. The model predicts realistic differences between desert cities and cities located on productive agricultural land, as well as differences between cities with expensive vs. cheap commuting and high vs. low incomes. The model is a useful and powerful tool for understanding urban spatial structure. 19. The net effect of these simultaneous changes is an upward shift in the housing-price curve, which leads to a decrease in dwelling size q at all locations. The higher p curve generates an upward shift in the land-rent curve, leading to an increase in building heights at all locations. Population density rises at all locations. The open-city effects of a higher t (and the accompanying decrease in L ; see note 18) are the reverse of the effects of a higher y , just as in the closed-city case. In contrast, in an open city, a higher r A (and the accompanying decrease in L ) has no effect on p , q , r , building height, or D . The only effect is a shrinkage of the city’s land area. See Brueckner 1987 for details. Brueckner, J. K. (2011). Lectures on urban economics. MIT Press. Created from utoronto on 2023-10-19 18:36:09. Copyright © 2011. MIT Press. All rights reserved.
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
  • Access to all documents
  • Unlimited textbook solutions
  • 24/7 expert homework help

Browse Popular Homework Q&A

Q: patient with chronic bronchitis has developed secondary polycythemia.  What caused this?  (Hint:…
Q: H2O X He
Q: 4. Find (f-g)(x) if f(x) = -2x + 4 and g(x)=x²-3x+5. O (f-g)(x) = -x²+x-1 O (f-g)(x)=x²-5x +9 O…
Q: Use the quadratic formula to solve for x. 2x² +6x+1=0 (If there is more than one solution, separate…
Q: ind the derivative of: −4e−3xcos(−8x)-4e-3xcos(-8x) Now, find the equation of the tangent…
Q: Let A-R\(-2), and define f: A-R by the formula f(a) a but not onto. 2a a+2 Prove that is one-to-one
Q: QUESTION 8 What is the first row of a direct cosine matrix from a space A to a space B knowing that:…
Q: Since non-probability sampling is faster, cheaper, and easier then probability sampling it should be…
Q: plans to leave it for 10 years. (Round your final answers to two decimal places.) (a) Find the…
Q: What exactly is a biased exponent, and in what ways may using one be beneficial?
Q: {(u-1 + ₂u^)u} (3) 1-n)}
Q: Use the accompanying tables of Laplace transforms and properties of Laplace transforms to find the…
Q: Estimate the moment of inertia of a bicycle wheel 67 cm in diameter. The rim and tire have a…
Q: Name 5 different physiological systems that are influenced by drugs
Q: The temperature during a very cold day is recorded every 2 hours for 12 hours. The data are given in…
Q: Question 12 of 12 The pOH of 0.0140 M solution of Sr(OH)2 is
Q: I'm sorry, the solution is incorrect
Q: Consider the indefinite integral Je+ 7x+4 dx: a) This can be transformed into a basic integral by…
Q: Jean Piaget believed:   a. zone of proximal development.   b. the child’s interaction with the…
Q: Can i get help step by step
Q: What do you think the biggest important distinctions are between a traditional phone network and the…
Q: Use the Ratio Test to determine whether the series is convergent or divergent. Σ n = 1 Identify an-…