final_practice_solutions
pdf
keyboard_arrow_up
School
University of California, Berkeley *
*We aren’t endorsed by this school
Course
121
Subject
Economics
Date
Feb 20, 2024
Type
Pages
12
Uploaded by LieutenantReindeer2533
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
ECON 121: (Practice) Final Exam
Answers
Name:
Points:
Instructions.
You have 140 minutes to complete this exam. The exam has a total of 110 points. Please
answer each question in the space assigned for it. For problems, please box your final answer. If you run
out of space, you can continue your answer on the back of the page. In that case, please be very clear about
where each question continues. You are allowed to use a calculator. Phones and laptops or tables are not
allowed.
Short-answer questions (40 points)
This section includes short questions. For each question, you must answer the question and provide a brief
explanation. We suggest you to provide brief and precise answers. You can use plots to support your answers
whenever useful.
1. (5 points) Describe the difference between average cost and marginal cost. Explain how they relate to
the short-run and long-run equilibrium in competitive markets.
Answer:
The average cost (AC(q)) function of a firm is the minimum cost per unit produced. The
marginal cost of production (MC(q)) is the increase in (total) costs if output is increased marginally.
It is the rate of change in total cost with respect to output.
AC
=
TC
Q
MC
=
∆
TC
∆
Q
The AC and MC curve dictate the short-run equilibrium of the firm. Firms will operate where
P
=
MC
in competitive markets. This point allows us to figure out what the quasi-rents are for a firm. Quasi-
rents per unit of production are the difference between the price and the average cost of production.
All operationg firms in the short-run should have postive quasi
In the long run, the price in a competitive market is the minimum long-run average cost. That is in
the long run firms will produce
q
mes
.
2. (5 points) Explain why is it a problem for demand estimation that prices are endogenous.
Answer:
The problem with endogenous prices is that we cannot use just a goods price and market quanity sold
to identify the demand function. Many other factors determine the price and quanity sold in a market.
For example, There are characteristics of goods that we dont see in data. This is importnat because
it could be the case that some products with unobserved characteristics will have higher prices due to
those properties.
Also, price and quanity are equilibirum relationships. That is, they are determined by the interaction
of supply and demand.
So we cannot just use the price and quanity sold to identify the demand
function because we need to know what variation in the market is due to demand and what is due to
supply.
1
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
3. (5 points) Explain briefly what is the Structure-Conduct-Performance framework to study anti-trust
policy.
Answer:
The idea is to back out how firms are behaving in the market by using the measuring and studying
how a market is strucutred. Stucture is usually measured using some measure of concentration in the
market like HHI. Then we collect data on the preformace of the firms in the market. This typically
means data on profitability. The stastical analysis is then to see if there is a relationship between the
structure of the market and the preformance of the firms. If there is a relationship, then we can infer
that the firms are behaving in a way that is consistent with a market structure that is not competitive.
4. (5 points) Give two examples of way in which firms can invest to increase the barriers to entry.
Answer:
(a) Clientele and switching costs: - Reduces consumer demand for potential entrant - More so the
when consumer information is poor, or switching costs high - ’Loyalty revolution’ in market-
ing/promotions 1980s
(b) Franchise networks: - Incumbent can contract with more able franchisees in the market - Exclusive
dealing allows for limiting access to them by entrant
(c) Physical capital
Many others.
5. (5 points) Explain what is double marginalization and how it can be avoided.
Answer:
Double marginlization is when there are two firms in a vertical chain and both firms have market
power. The downstream firm will set a price that is above marginal cost and the upstream firm will
set a price that is above marginal cost. This double mark-up leads to inefficent prices and quanities in
the market.
This can be avoide by vertical integration. That is, if the upstream firm buys the downstream firm
then the upstream firm can set the downstream price at marginal cost.
This can also be solved by
contracts between the upstream and downstream firms. This is dicussed a bit in the book.
6. (5 points) In Farronato, Fong & Fradkin (2023) "Dog Eat Dog: Balancing Network Effects and Dif-
ferentiation in a Digital Platform Merger", the authors study the merger of two dog sitting platforms.
They find that consumers are not better off with a single dominant platform compared to two com-
petitors. Explain what are the three possible forces driving consumer well-being. Which one explains
the result in their setting?
Answer:
•
Network effects: more users on a platform increase the value of the platform for all users
•
Product differentiation: different platforms offer different features
•
Customer Match Quality: repeat users can match with the the same users.
From the paper: "We find support for two related mechanisms that partially explain these effects: a
coordination failure and disintermediation, whereby DogVacay buyers have a harder time finding their
previous providers on Rover and may be led to transact with those same providers off the platform.
Attrition by Dogvacay buyers almost perfectly offsets the increased usage of Rover buyers so that
at the market level, we find no evidence that the combined platform substantially improves market
outcomes compared to the sum of the two separate platforms: not on the extensive margins such as
user adoption, retention or total transactions, nor on the intensive margins, such as match rates or
ratings"
2
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
The reduction in matching quality at the market level tends to perfeclty offset the benefit from the
network effects from the merger. Showing that its not always the case that mergers increasing network
effects are good for consumers.
7. (5 points) You want to estimate demand. Explain why you need two instruments to estimate a nested
logit model.
Answer:
We need two instruments to identify the demand function because we have two endogenous variables
in the demand function now. The nested logit model has two endogenous variables, the market share
of the nest and the market share of the product within the nest. P and Q are still endognesou even
within the nest. Nests dont solve the endogeneity problem, they solve the weird cross-price elasticities
that the IIA assumption creates. When we use a nest, we are making a strong assumption on consumer
behavior for those products in the market.
8. (5 points) Explain how price competition affects the incentives to differentiate.
Answer:
Price competition with homogeneous products drives economic profits to zero.
But if a firm can
differentiate their product, then they can charge a higher price and earn positive profits. Check out
slide 9 of lecture 11 for more details.
Problems (70 points)
1.
Merger analysis.
(20 points) Two Cournot duopolists produce in a market with demand
P
= 100
−
Q
.
The marginal cost for firm 1 is constant and equals 10. The marginal cost for firm 2 is also constant and
it equals 25. The two firms want to merge. They argue for the merger on the grounds that marginal
production costs would fall to 10 for all units of output after the merger since all production would
be at the low marginal cost. You work in the Anti Trust division of the Department of Justice (DOJ)
and need to decide whether to allow the merger or not based on whether consumer surplus goes up or
down. Consumer surplus is given by
CS
(
P
) =
(100
−
P
)
2
2
.
(a) (5 points) Find equilibrium prices and quantities in the absence of the merger.
Answer:
Firm 1:
max
q
1
π
1
= (100
−
q
1
−
q
2
)
q
1
−
10
q
1
∂π
1
∂q
1
= 100
−
2
q
1
−
q
2
−
10 = 0
q
1
= 45
−
q
2
2
Firm 2:
max
q
2
π
2
= (100
−
q
1
−
q
2
)
q
2
−
25
q
2
∂π
2
∂q
2
= 100
−
q
1
−
2
q
2
−
25 = 0
q
2
= 37
.
5
−
q
1
2
The equilibrium quantity is given by
q
1
= 45
−
37
.
5
−
q
1
2
2
= 35
and
q
2
= 37
.
5
−
45
−
q
2
2
2
= 20
. The
equilbrium price is
P
= 100
−
35
−
20 = 45
.
3
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
(b) (2 points) Calculate profits and consumer surplus in the absence of the merger.
Answer:
Firm 1’s profits are
π
1
= (45)(45
−
10) = 1575
and firm 2’s profits are
π
2
= (20)(45
−
25) = 400
.
Total profits are
π
= 1575 + 400 = 1975
. Consumer surplus is
CS
=
(100
−
45)
2
2
= 1512
.
5
.
Total surplus is
TS
=
CS
+
π
= 1975 +
(100
−
45)
2
2
= 3487
.
5
.
(c) (5 points) Find equilibrium prices and quantities after the merger assuming that the new marginal
cost is 10. After the merger, the new marginal cost is 10 and it becomes a monopoly problem.
Answer:
Monopolist:
max
q
π
= (100
−
q
)
q
−
10
q
∂π
∂q
= 100
−
2
q
−
10 = 0
q
= 45
Equilibrium quantity is
q
= 45
and equilibrium price is
P
= 100
−
45 = 55
.
(d) (2 points) Calculate profits and consumer surplus under the merger. Would you allow the merger?
Answer:
Profits are
π
= (45)(55
−
10) = 2025
. Consumer surplus is
CS
=
(100
−
55)
2
2
= 1012
.
5
.
We only allow the merge if CS is higher than without the merger. In this case, CS is lower than
without the merger, so we would not allow the merger.
(e) (2 points) Is there any reduction in costs that would justify the merger?
If so, calculate the
marginal cost that both firms would need to achieve to justify the merger.
Answer:
Here we are now asking what is the marginal cost that would make the DOJ indifferent to the
Competition outcome. That is, we want to find
c
such that
CS
Monopoly
(
c
) =
CS
Cournot
.
We need to find the monoplist equilibirum price as a function of
c
.
Monopolist:
max
q
π
= (100
−
q
)
q
−
cq
∂π
∂q
= 100
−
2
q
−
c
= 0
q
= 50
−
c
2
That means the equilibrium price is
P
= 100
−
50 +
c
2
= 50 +
c
2
. So then the consumer surplus is
CS
=
(100
−
(50+
c
2
))
2
2
=
(50+
c
2
)
2
2
.
Great, now lets equate the two consumer surpluses and solve for
c
.
(50 +
c
2
)
2
2
=
1512
.
5
(50 +
c
2
)
2
= 3025
50
−
c
= 55
c
=
−
10
To justify the merger, the marginal cost would need to be
c
=
−
10
. That is, the marginal cost
would need to be negative. This is not possible, so the merger is not justified based on CS.
4
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
(f) (4 points) Now suppose that instead of maximizing consumer surplus, the DOJ is interested in
maximizing total welfare (i.e., profits + consumer surplus). At what post-merger cost you would
be indifferent between allowing the merger or not?
Answer:
Here we are now asking what is the marginal cost that would make the DOJ indifferent to the Com-
petition outcome. That is, we want to find
c
such that
TS
Monopoly
(
c
) =
TS
Cournot
.
We need to find the monoplist profits as a
c
now and use that with our CS we found in the previous
part.
That means the equilibrium price is
P
= 50 +
c
2
and the equilibrium quantity is
q
= 50
−
c
2
. So profits
are
π
= (50
−
c
2
)(50 +
c
2
−
c
) = (50
−
c
2
)
2
.
TS
=
CS
+
π
=
(50
−
c
2
)
2
2
+ (50
−
c
2
)
2
Now equate that to the total surplus we had in the Cournot case and solve for
c
.
(50
−
c
2
)
2
2
+ (50
−
c
2
)
2
=
3487
.
5
(50
−
c
2
)
2
+ 2(50
−
c
2
)
2
=
6975
3(50
−
c
2
)
2
=
6975
(50
−
c
2
)
2
=
2325
50
−
c
2
=
√
2325
100
−
2
√
2325
=
c
c
∼
3
.
5
s
5
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
2.
Increasing rivals’ costs.
(10 points) Suppose that a competitive fringe produces with costs given by
C
= 4
q
f
. Demand is given by
P
= 20
−
Q
and the dominant firm’s costs are given by
C
=
q
2
.
(a) (5 points) Compute the dominant firm’s profits in equilibrium.
Answer:
Whats the catch here?
The dominant firm is a monopoly, but the fringe is competitive.
what
does it mean to be a competitive market? It means that the fringe is a price taker. But what
does that really imply? It means that the fringe will produce where
P
=
MC
f
.
Since we let the fringe firms market play out first they dictate the market price. Hence the market
price
P
=
MC
f
= 4
. Now the monopolist takes this price as given and solves their problem.
Dominant firm:
max
Q
π
= 4
Q
−
Q
2
∂π
∂Q
= 4
−
2
Q
= 0
Q
= 2
The dominate firms profits are
π
= 4(2)
−
2
2
= 4
.
(b) (5 points) Suppose that the dominant firm is able to cause an increase in the fringe’s marginal
costs of $2 at a cost of
κ
. For which values of
κ
would the dominant firm decide to increase the
fringe’s marginal cost?
Answer:
Now this is a problem of comparing the profits of the dominant firm with and without the increase in
marginal costs to the fringe.
We solved in part (a) that the dominant firm’s profits are
π
= 4
. When they don’t increase the marginal
cost of the fringe. Now we need to redo the problem with the increase in marginal cost of the fringe
and the loss of profits from the dominant firm from
κ
.
With the increase in marginal cost, the fringe will set the EQ price where
P
= 6
.
Dominant firm:
max
Q
π
= 6
Q
−
Q
2
∂π
∂Q
= 6
−
2
Q
= 0
Q
= 3
The dominate firms profits are
π
= 6(3)
−
3
2
−
κ
= 9
−
κ
.
The dominant firm will increase the marginal cost of the fringe if the profits from doing so are greater
than the profits without doing so.
9
−
κ
=
4
κ
=
5
So the dominant firm will increase the marginal cost of the fringe if the cost of doing so is less or equal
to
κ
= 5
.
6
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
3.
Hotelling city with network externalities.
(20 points) Consider a linear Hotelling city with
network externalities. Consumers are uniformly distributed between
0
and
1
. Firm A is located at the
left end of the city, at
x
= 0
and firm B is located at the right end of the city, at
x
= 1
. A consumer
located at
x
∈
[0
,
1]
obtains a utility
u
Ax
=
v
−
p
A
−
x
2
+
θq
e
A
from using the platform offered by A
and
u
Bx
=
v
−
p
B
−
(1
−
x
)
2
+
θq
e
B
from using the platform offered by B, where
v
is the common
valuation for the platform,
θ >
0
is a fixed parameter measuring the intensity of network effects, and
q
e
A
and
q
e
B
are the expectations about the number of consumers consuming each platform. Firm A has
a marginal cost of production
c
A
= 1
and firm B has marginal cost of production
c
B
= 2
. Assume that
v
is sufficiently large so that the market is covered in equilibrium. Expectations are rational (i.e., in
equilibrium
q
e
A
=
q
A
and
q
e
B
=
q
B
) and passive (expectations do not respond to changes in prices).
(a) (3 points) Find the location of the consumer who is indifferent between consuming the goods from
A and B as a function of
(
p
A
, p
B
, θ, q
e
A
, q
e
B
)
.
Answer:
u
Ax
=
u
Bx
v
−
p
A
−
x
2
+
θq
e
A
=
v
−
p
B
−
(1
−
x
)
2
+
θq
e
B
p
B
−
p
A
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
) + 1
2
=
x
(b) (4 points) Obtain the best-response functions for both firms.
Answer:
Firm A:
max
p
A
π
A
= (
p
A
−
1)(
p
B
−
p
A
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
) + 1
2
)
∂π
A
∂p
A
=
p
B
2
−
p
A
2
+
1
2
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
)
2
+
1
−
p
A
2
= 0
p
B
−
p
A
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
) + 1
2
+
1
2
−
p
A
2
= 0
p
B
−
p
A
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
) + 1 + 1
−
p
A
= 0
p
B
+ 2
−
2
p
A
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
) = 0
p
A
=
p
B
+ 2 +
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
)
2
Firm B:
max
p
B
π
B
= (
p
B
−
2)(1
−
p
B
−
p
A
+ 1 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
)
∂π
B
∂p
B
= (1)(1
−
p
B
−
p
A
+ 1 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
) + (
p
B
−
2)(
−
1
2
) = 0
1
−
p
B
−
p
A
+ 1 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
−
p
B
−
2
2
= 0
1 +
p
A
−
p
B
−
1
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
+
2
−
p
B
2
= 0
2 +
p
A
−
p
B
−
1
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) + 2
−
p
B
= 0
3 +
p
A
−
2
p
B
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) = 0
p
B
=
p
A
+ 3
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
7
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
(c) (5 points) Obtain the equilibrium prices as a function of
(
θ, q
e
A
, q
e
B
)
.
Answer:
p
A
=
p
B
+ 2 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
p
A
=
p
A
+3
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
+ 2 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
p
A
=
p
A
4
+
3
4
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
4
+ 1 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
3
4
p
A
=
7
4
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
4
+
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
3
p
A
=
7
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) + 2
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
p
A
=
7
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) + 2
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
p
A
=
7 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
p
A
=
7
3
+
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
Sub in the above into the best response function for firm B.
p
B
=
p
A
+ 3
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
p
B
=
7
3
+
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
+ 3
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
p
B
=
7
6
+
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
6
+
3
2
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
2
p
B
=
8
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
(d) (5 points) Obtain the equilibrium quantity
q
A
as a function of
θ
. [Hint:
q
A
+
q
B
= 1
]
Answer:
Now to do this, you need to recall that in hotelling models
q
A
=
x
and
q
B
= 1
−
x
. All we need
for this though is
q
A
=
x
.
8
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
q
A
=
x
q
A
=
p
B
−
p
A
+
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
) + 1
2
q
A
=
8
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
−
(
7
3
+
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
3
) +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) + 1
2
Multiply by 6:
6
q
A
=
8
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
−
7
−
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) + 3
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
) + 3
6
q
A
=
4 +
θ
(
q
e
A
−
q
e
B
)
Recall in equilibirum
q
A
=
q
e
A
, q
B
=
q
e
B
and
q
B
= 1
−
q
A
6
q
A
=
4 +
θ
(
q
A
−
q
B
)
6
q
A
=
4 +
θ
(
q
A
−
(1
−
q
A
))
6
q
A
=
4 +
θ
(2
q
A
−
1)
6
q
A
=
4 + 2
θq
A
−
θ
q
A
=
4
−
θ
6
−
2
θ
(e) (3 points) For what values of
θ
does
A
cover the whole market?
Answer:
A covers the whole market when
q
A
= 1
.
q
A
=
1
4
−
θ
6
−
2
θ
= 1
6
−
2
θ
=
4
−
θ
2
=
θ
9
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
4.
Vertical integration.
(20 points) In 1968, the Supreme Court decided a case involving the publisher
of a St. Louis newspaper and one of the carriers that delivered the newspaper to individual households.
The publisher had established a system in which each carrier was granted an exclusive territory that was
subject to termination if the carrier charged a retail price for the newspaper exceeding the maximum
price suggested by the publisher. In 1961, the carrier for Route 99 raised the price for its customers to
a level that exceeded the suggested maximum retail price. The publisher took retaliatory actions that
eventually caused the carrier to lose the route, and the carrier sued for treble damages under Section 1
of the Sherman Act. The Supreme Court decided that enforcing resale price restrictions in this manner
constituted per se illegal price-fixing.
To model this situation, let the inverse demand function for newspapers on Route 99 be
P
= 100
−
Q
, where
Q
denotes the number of newspapers sold in the route.
The publisher’s marginal cost
of producing newspapers is a constant given by
c
= 5
.
Suppose that the carrier incurs a constant
marginal delivery cost denoted by
d
= 2
. The carrier pays a wholesale price
w
and sells papers at a
retail price
P
. Both the carrier and the publisher are profit maximizers.
(a) (7 points) Suppose that resale price restrictions could be enforced legally, so the publisher chooses
the prices
w
and
P
.
Find equilibrium prices and quantities.
Calculate the publisher’s profit.
Answer:
This problem is different from what we showed in Lecture 20.
Here we are complelty remov-
ing the carrier/retailers opitmization problem. That is, once we find the publishers monopolist
maxmiinzng profit price level we force the retailer to sell at that price that just coveres their costs.
Said another way, the publisher ignores the carrier’s downstream and treats their cost as apart of
their own marginal cost. Here the problem is like the monopolist makes, publishes and distrubutes
the newspaper. They do not have to worry about the carrier downstream. Vertically integrated
monopolist problem:
Publisher:
max
P
π
= (100
−
P
)(
p
−
5
−
2)
Publisher:
max
P
π
= (100
−
P
)(
p
−
7)
∂π
∂P
= 100
−
2
P
+ 7 = 0
P
=
107
2
=
∼
$53
.
5
The equilibirum quanity of newspapers is
100
−
107
2
=
93
2
.
Now since the publisher has complete control of the vertical market, they can force the carrier to
sell at the price
P
=
107
2
. Which means when they set
w
they need to set it such that the carrier
makes zero profits. This is because
w
is a cost to the carrier downstream, and if the publisher
controls the whole vertical market then any increases of
w
above the marginal cost of the carrier is
the same as the publisher volentairly increasing their own MC which in turn reduces their profits.
Hence, the carrier will set
w
=
P
−
d
, inturn making the carrier have zero profits.
So then the equilibirum
w
is
w
=
107
2
−
2 =
103
2
Profits are
10
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
π
= (100
−
107
2
)(
107
2
−
5
−
2)
93
2
·
93
2
= 2162
.
5
(b) (7 points) Now suppose that resale price restrictions cannot be legally enforced, so the carrier is
free to choose
P
. Let
w
′
and
P
′
denote the equilibrium prices without the resale price restriction.
Find equilibrium prices and quantities. Will
P
′
be greater than or less than te equilibrium price
from (a)?
Answer:
To solve these vertical integration problems,we need to solve backwards. That is we need to start
at the bottom of the market structure and work up the vertical chain.
So we start with the
carrier’s problem. Below follows the flow of the Double Marginilzation slides in the Lecture 20.
We solve two monopoly problems in a row. First the carrier’s problem and then the publisher’s
problem, where we use the results from the carrier’s problem.
Carrier:
max
p
π
= (100
−
p
)(
p
−
2
−
w
)
∂π
∂p
= 102
−
2
p
+
w
= 0
p
=
102 +
w
2
The equilibirum quanity of newspapers is
100
−
102 +
w
2
q
= 49
−
w
2
Now we use this quanitty in the publisher’s problem. Where the publisher picks
w
to maximize
their profits.
Publisher:
max
w
π
= (
w
−
5)(49
−
w
2
)
Publisher:
max
w
π
=
1
2
[103
w
−
w
2
−
245]
∂π
∂w
= 103
−
2
w
= 0
w
= 51
.
5
The equilibirum price is the
153
.
2
2
= 76
.
75
and the equilibrium quantity is
23
.
25
.
We can see that the equilibrium price is higher than the price in part (a). This is caused by the
double- marginilzation that happens when the publisher and carrier are not vertically integrated.
You can graphically see this relationship below. We just solved for
P
D
M
in part (a) we found
P
∗
.
(c) (3 points) Does making maximum resale prices illegal improve consumer surplus? Here we are
asking is CS bigger in (a) or (b)?
11
Econ 121, Practice Exam
Instructor: Nano Barahona
Answer:
Consumer surplus is
CS
=
(100
−
53
.
5)
2
2
= 1081
.
125
in (a) and
CS
=
(100
−
76
.
75)
2
2
=
∼
270
in (b).
Clearly the CS is large in
(
a
)
than in
(
b
)
. You can also see this below in the graph. The area of
the triangle is smaller in
(
b
)
than in
(
a
)
.
(d) (3 points) Suppose that the carrier’s demand depends on its selling effort,
s
, and that it chooses
s
to maximize its own profit. Would the carrier make any effort under the solution from (a)?
Answer:
No the carrier would not make any effort under the solution from (a). In part (a) this contracting
solution, typcially called "complete contracting" solution, the publisher has made the carrier’s
profits = 0. So the carrier has no incentive to make any effort. Other contracting options exist
such that seller effort would increase profits for both the publisher and the carrier.
12
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
Related Documents
Recommended textbooks for you

Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:9781337106665
Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Economics Today and Tomorrow, Student Edition
Economics
ISBN:9780078747663
Author:McGraw-Hill
Publisher:Glencoe/McGraw-Hill School Pub Co

Microeconomics: Principles & Policy
Economics
ISBN:9781337794992
Author:William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. Solow
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Essentials of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:9781337091992
Author:N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:9781337617383
Author:Roger A. Arnold
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Recommended textbooks for you
- Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving ApproachEconomicsISBN:9781337106665Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike ShorPublisher:Cengage LearningEconomics Today and Tomorrow, Student EditionEconomicsISBN:9780078747663Author:McGraw-HillPublisher:Glencoe/McGraw-Hill School Pub CoMicroeconomics: Principles & PolicyEconomicsISBN:9781337794992Author:William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. SolowPublisher:Cengage Learning
- Essentials of Economics (MindTap Course List)EconomicsISBN:9781337091992Author:N. Gregory MankiwPublisher:Cengage LearningEconomics (MindTap Course List)EconomicsISBN:9781337617383Author:Roger A. ArnoldPublisher:Cengage Learning

Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:9781337106665
Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Economics Today and Tomorrow, Student Edition
Economics
ISBN:9780078747663
Author:McGraw-Hill
Publisher:Glencoe/McGraw-Hill School Pub Co

Microeconomics: Principles & Policy
Economics
ISBN:9781337794992
Author:William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. Solow
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Essentials of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:9781337091992
Author:N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:9781337617383
Author:Roger A. Arnold
Publisher:Cengage Learning
