In Italy, the procurement of public works has seen a significant shift in methodology since 1999, with most projects being awarded through an innovative auction format. This method determines the winning bidder as the one whose bid is closest to a function of the average of all bids. This shift was inspired by an idea introduced in the early 1990s by two engineering professors, loannou and Leu. In their 1993 paper, they criticized the standard first-price auction and proposed an alternative sealed bid auction where the bid closest to a calculated threshold-often based on the average bid-determines the winner. This approach was developed to address the issues of excessively high bids that might compromise the quality or feasibility of the demanded work. In addition to Italy, this auction format has been adopted by several countries, including Colombia, Italy, China, Chile, Japan, Peru, and Taiwan, reflecting its global relevance. Despite the initial promise, the implementation of average-bid auctions has not been without challenges. These auctions have inadvertently fostered new forms of strategic bidding behavior, leading to unforeseen complexities and issues. The strategies employed by bidders in these auctions sometimes create larger problems than those they were meant to solve, casting doubts on the overall efficacy of the average-bid auction format. The goal of this exercise is to investigate a simple version of this auction in the case of private values. The setup mirrors closely what we discussed in class, featuring an auction for a single item. For simplicity, let's consider only two bidders participating. Each bidder's valuation is uniformly distributed independently within the interval [0, 100]. The rules of the auction are as follows: The highest bid secures the object. Only the winner is required to make a payment. • The amount paid by the winner is the average of the two bids (i.e., the sum of both bids divided by two). Question a. What is the Nash equilibrium of this game? Question b.It was commonly believed that an average-bid auction will generate higher revenues than either a first-price or second-price sealed-bid auction. Is there any truth to this view? What is the expected revenue for the seller in such an auction? • .

ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
14th Edition
ISBN:9780190931919
Author:NEWNAN
Publisher:NEWNAN
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
icon
Related questions
Question
None
In Italy, the procurement of public works has seen a significant shift in methodology since 1999, with most projects being awarded
through an innovative auction format. This method determines the winning bidder as the one whose bid is closest to a function of
the average of all bids. This shift was inspired by an idea introduced in the early 1990s by two engineering professors, loannou
and Leu. In their 1993 paper, they criticized the standard first-price auction and proposed an alternative sealed bid auction where
the bid closest to a calculated threshold-often based on the average bid-determines the winner. This approach was developed
to address the issues of excessively high bids that might compromise the quality or feasibility of the demanded work. In addition
to Italy, this auction format has been adopted by several countries, including Colombia, Italy, China, Chile, Japan, Peru, and
Taiwan, reflecting its global relevance. Despite the initial promise, the implementation of average-bid auctions has not been
without challenges. These auctions have inadvertently fostered new forms of strategic bidding behavior, leading to unforeseen
complexities and issues. The strategies employed by bidders in these auctions sometimes create larger problems than those
they were meant to solve, casting doubts on the overall efficacy of the average-bid auction format. The goal of this exercise is to
investigate a simple version of this auction in the case of private values. The setup mirrors closely what we discussed in class,
featuring an auction for a single item. For simplicity, let's consider only two bidders participating. Each bidder's valuation is
uniformly distributed independently within the interval [0, 100]. The rules of the auction are as follows: The highest bid secures
the object. Only the winner is required to make a payment. • The amount paid by the winner is the average of the two bids (i.e.,
the sum of both bids divided by two). Question a. What is the Nash equilibrium of this game? Question b.It was commonly believed
that an average-bid auction will generate higher revenues than either a first-price or second-price sealed-bid auction. Is there any
truth to this view? What is the expected revenue for the seller in such an auction?
•
.
Transcribed Image Text:In Italy, the procurement of public works has seen a significant shift in methodology since 1999, with most projects being awarded through an innovative auction format. This method determines the winning bidder as the one whose bid is closest to a function of the average of all bids. This shift was inspired by an idea introduced in the early 1990s by two engineering professors, loannou and Leu. In their 1993 paper, they criticized the standard first-price auction and proposed an alternative sealed bid auction where the bid closest to a calculated threshold-often based on the average bid-determines the winner. This approach was developed to address the issues of excessively high bids that might compromise the quality or feasibility of the demanded work. In addition to Italy, this auction format has been adopted by several countries, including Colombia, Italy, China, Chile, Japan, Peru, and Taiwan, reflecting its global relevance. Despite the initial promise, the implementation of average-bid auctions has not been without challenges. These auctions have inadvertently fostered new forms of strategic bidding behavior, leading to unforeseen complexities and issues. The strategies employed by bidders in these auctions sometimes create larger problems than those they were meant to solve, casting doubts on the overall efficacy of the average-bid auction format. The goal of this exercise is to investigate a simple version of this auction in the case of private values. The setup mirrors closely what we discussed in class, featuring an auction for a single item. For simplicity, let's consider only two bidders participating. Each bidder's valuation is uniformly distributed independently within the interval [0, 100]. The rules of the auction are as follows: The highest bid secures the object. Only the winner is required to make a payment. • The amount paid by the winner is the average of the two bids (i.e., the sum of both bids divided by two). Question a. What is the Nash equilibrium of this game? Question b.It was commonly believed that an average-bid auction will generate higher revenues than either a first-price or second-price sealed-bid auction. Is there any truth to this view? What is the expected revenue for the seller in such an auction? • .
Expert Solution
trending now

Trending now

This is a popular solution!

steps

Step by step

Solved in 2 steps

Blurred answer
Recommended textbooks for you
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
Economics
ISBN:
9780190931919
Author:
NEWNAN
Publisher:
Oxford University Press
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education