greco-2021-textbook-economics-from-ameritrade-s-joe-ricketts
pdf
keyboard_arrow_up
School
University of Ottawa *
*We aren’t endorsed by this school
Course
1192
Subject
Economics
Date
Jan 9, 2024
Type
Pages
11
Uploaded by DrFog12475
Studies in Microeconomics
11(2) 195–205, 2023
© The Author(s) 2021
Article reuse guidelines:
in.sagepub.com/journals-
permissions-india
DOI: 10.1177/23210222211051448
journals.sagepub.com/home/mic
Policy Analysis and Debate
Textbook Economics from
Ameritrade’s Joe Ricketts
Anthony J. Greco
1
Abstract
This article reviews the history of Ameritrade founded and developed by Joe
Ricketts into a spectacularly successful discount brokerage enterprise. It, as such,
represents another example of a risk-taking innovator who achieves success by
filling a need in a free-enterprise market. The main takeaway is that free-enterprise
works best from the bottom-up, that is, when individuals or individual companies
‘creatively destruct’ existing markets or generate new markets for goods or
services through the implementation of innovative ideas and technology. The
article also delineates the workings of the free-enterprise market by pointing
out how familiar textbook economic principles are illustrated in the Ameritrade
experience.
JEL Classifications:
A10, D01, E02, G10
Keywords
Choice under uncertainty, market equilibrium, microeconomics, producer
choice, rational choice, individual decision-making
Introduction
The founding of Ameritrade by Joe Ricketts and its ultimate spectacular success
as a discount brokerage firm is yet another example of what can happen in the
free-enterprise system of the U.S. economy when ‘creative destruction’ occurs.
Over time, the firm, now TD Ameritrade after its merger with TD Waterhouse in
2004, became the number one online broker as measured by trading volume
(Ricketts, 2019, pp. 292–293).
1
Department of Economics and Finance, University of Louisiana-Lafayette, Lafayette, Louisiana, USA
Corresponding author:
Anthony J. Greco, Department of Economics and Finance, University of Louisiana-Lafayette,
Lafayette, Louisiana 70504, USA.
E-mail: ajg1979@louisiana.edu
196
Studies in Microeconomics 11(2)
Joseph Schumpeter originated the term ‘creative destruction’ essentially to
describe the process of moving from the status quo in a market to positive changes
that enhance efficiency and progress in that market and, perhaps, in others, as
well. While it is undoubtedly a process that involves risk and uncertainty on the
part of innovative entrepreneurs, it is a process vital to economic progress
(Spiegel, 1971, p. 545).
As in earlier and contemporaneous instances of innovative destruction, the
Ameritrade experience illustrates basic microeconomic principles at work. After
briefly discussing the history of Ameritrade, this paper examines some of the
relevant textbook examples of said principles shown in the Ameritrade experience.
The Founding and Development of Ameritrade
There are essentially three markets involving the trading of stocks. In the ‘first
market’, stocks are purchased directly from the issuers of the stock. The ‘second
market’ involves the purchase of stock from the traditional stock exchange, such
as the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE). The ‘third market’ or ‘over-the-
counter’ market is where stocks are traded through a third-party securities trader
not bound by the rules or commissions applicable to the stock exchange. This
‘over-the-counter’ market is now referred to as ‘Nasdaq’ which is the National
Association of Securities Dealers Automated Quotations (Ricketts, 2019, p. 61).
As the reader has deduced, Joe Ricketts recently related the Ameritrade story
in an informative and interesting memoir referred to liberally in this study. The
company was originally formed by Ricketts and a colleague at Dean Witter along
with the two principals at a small brokerage firm in Omaha, Nebraska in early
1975. It was called First Omaha Securities. Stockbroker commissions were non-
negotiable, at that time, having been fixed by the predecessor of the NYSE over
180 years before. However, due to antitrust concerns the federal government
decided to phase out fixed commissions as of May 1975 beginning with the
highest dollar trades (Ricketts, 2019, p. 56).
At that time, the trading of stocks ‘over-the-counter’ through third-party
securities dealers (‘the third market’ alluded to previously) was in its early stages
of development. It was ignored by many brokers who believed that it would be
best to maintain their ongoing commissions. Ricketts and his colleague, and his
original partner from Dean Witter, however, saw great opportunity in the third
market. Ricketts, unlike his partner, had no money to invest, but he found risk-
taking exciting. He reasoned that orders in the third market would come from
experienced and knowledgeable investors. That being the case, his firm could pay
an exchange broker for each evolving trade and offer its customers lower costs
through the elimination of the traditional services and functions of brokers. To
that end, the firm soon announced that it would provide for third-market trades for
a $25.00 fee (Ricketts, 2019, p. 71). Though Ricketts’ firm was actually providing
trades at commissions, its competitors attempted to tarnish its image by dubbing
it a ‘discount broker’ with the implication that the firm’s services were inferior to
those provided by full-service brokers (Ricketts, 2019, p. 72).
Greco
197
Initially, Ricketts offered trades exclusively on the regional Midwest Stock
Exchange thinking that as non-members of the NYSE, his firm could not offer
trades there. This again brought accusations from the firm’s full-service
competitors that it offered an inferior service. However, Ricketts and company
learned that one could trade as a non-member on the NYSE if one paid a higher
price ($8–$12 more per trade). This could, therefore, reduce the firm’s $25.00
commission per trade by nearly 50%. Though apprehensive, the partners decided
to pursue this alternative (Ricketts, 2019, p. 74).
Ultimately, Ricketts bought out his partners in 1982, he established subsidiaries
to explore possibilities that had been previously vetoed by his partners. The retail
operation of stock trades for individual investors was named First Natural
Brokerage. A second subsidiary First Natural Futures, Inc, provided retail trading
in commodities. The third subsidiary, Ameritrade Clearing, involved an expansion
of the firm’s clearing services to meet the demand for such small retail broker-
dealers attracted by the firm’s lower commissions. As such, this constituted a
discount wholesale operation. These three operations were consolidated as
Ameritrade in 1985 (Ricketts, 2019, pp. 135–136, 153).
‘Clearing’ in stock trades essentially refers to what is done to complete the
market transaction between the buyer and seller of stock. It involves getting the
stock buyer’s money to the seller of the stock in exchange for the seller’s stock
certificate (a physical piece of paper with a stated monetary value, as well as, the
provisions of records of the trade to the two transacting parties, the stock exchange
and the government according to legal specifications) (Ricketts, 2019, p. 63).
Ricketts was aware of the growing feeling that the future of banking and
finance was in personal computers. However, he found, after about a year of
experimenting, that personal computers at that time (the 1980s) were too slow and
inefficient to be applied to his trading operations. Instead, he got the idea to
employ a simpler tool, the touch-tone phone. He directed his technology
department to design a software system allowing customers to use touch-tone
phones to request stock quotes and place orders. After much expense and time,
this innovation was introduced in 1988. Ricketts further innovated by offering
trades via the touch-tone system to retail customers for three cents a share.
Previously, in wholesale operations, Ricketts had paid brokers so many pennies
per share traded. He named the touch-tone service aspect of his business,
Accutrade. After establishing Accutrade, Ricketts firm had tremendous growth
(Ricketts, 2019, pp. 200–205).
Then, in 1995, Ameritrade learned that its biggest competitor, Charles Schwab,
had vertically integrated into the wholesale side of the industry by acquiring its
Nasdaq market maker. Such market makers were relied upon to maintain
inventories of stocks and provide continuous updates of their ‘bid’ (buying) and
‘ask’ (selling) prices of these stocks. The ‘spread’ was the difference between
these prices, and it constituted the profit earned by the market makers. By its
purchase, Charles Schwab owned the middleman and garnered the spread for
itself. Ricketts realized that Schwab could then lower the commissions they
charged allowing them to meet or undercut those charged by Ricketts (Rickets,
2019, pp. 228–229).
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
198
Studies in Microeconomics 11(2)
Other discount brokerages recognized this as well. Ricketts pondered the
creation of his own market maker to counter Schwab and, hence, eliminated the
cost involved in dealing with a middleman. However, a regulatory minimum
investment of $20 million was required to do so. Ricketts worked this out by
collaborating with other discount brokerage firms wherein the firms still competed
with one another for clients, but they shared their new high-tech market to service
their clients (Ricketts, 2019, pp. 229–230).
From its inception, Ameritrade had relied exclusively on advertising to generate
new accounts. However, the firm discovered in the 1990s that it could be more
efficient in this endeavour by acquiring smaller competitors. Eventually, it
considered the acquisition of a relatively large competitor. At that time, Ameritrade
and other industry leaders, such as Schwab, had touch-tone and computer dial-up
trading systems. However, the banks of telephone modems supporting these
systems were generally considered to be unreliable. The firm that Ameritrade was
considering to acquire, however, inaugurated trading stock over the Internet by
discount brokers in August 1994 through a proprietary email system. Though
lacking an expertise relative to the Internet, Ricketts foresaw its potential use by
the public in trading from their personal computers (Ricketts, 2019, pp.
236–237).
The company issued its initial public offering in March 1997 with shares priced
at $15.00 and finishing the day at $19.50. The company raised over $22 million
and experienced large stock price increase. In July 1997, Ricketts announced a
lowering of the per trade price to $8.00. Ricketts also pushed for $20 million in
advertising and a like amount on technology to support his trades (Ricketts, 2019,
p. 260).
After the implementation and continuance of the ad campaign, the numbers of
daily accounts opened by the company soared. It was maintained that each account
opened had a net present value of almost $1,300. For the next nine months the
company opened 181,000 accounts. At a net present value of $1,300.00 for each
of these accounts, the firm would have netted $235,300,000 over those nine
months. Ameritrade’s share of the total online brokerage market was then doubled
from September 1997 to June 1998 (from 3% to 6.4%). The company continued
to grow. It survived a downturn in the early 2000s and was eventually acquired by
TD Waterhouse in 2004 (Ricketts, 2019, pp. 263–264).
Recent Developments
In September 2017, TD Ameritrade acquired Scottrade, based in St. Louis,
Missouri. Then, in November 2019, Charles Schwab announced plans to acquire
the online brokerage of TD Ameritrade for approximately $26 billion in stock.
The sale was to close by the end of 2020, with the full integration of the companies
anticipated within 18–36 months. TD Ameritrade will remain a full-service broker
providing a wide variety of services, inclusive of investment research and
advising, retirement planning, and more, as well as online, discount trading
Greco
199
(commission-free trading) in stocks and other securities. Because of its value and
service quality, it is viewed as one of the best US brokerage firms. It boasts of
having over $1 trillion in customer assets and over 11 million client accounts
(Folger, 2021).
The last quarter century has witnessed a marked increase of discount brokerage
firms affording individuals the opportunity to invest in stocks inexpensively or
with no commission fee without the use of stockbrokers (Lemke, 2019). Prominent
among recent entrants are Robinhood and Webull. Robinhood, founded in 2013,
aided the revolution of online brokerage in 2014 by application of the simple fee
structure of commission-free trades on a mobile application for stocks and often
investments. It has thus attracted many new trades and investors. The company
quickly acquired over 6 million users. In addition to stock trading, Robinhood has
introduced other trading, such as cryptocurrency trading (Dave, 2020).
Webull was established in 2018 in direct competition with Robinhood. Webull
purports to having surpassed Robinhood in a fast two-year period by amassing
over 9 million users. Robinhood and Webull have expanded so rapidly because
they both offer new customers free stocks when they open accounts. In addition,
their popularity has grown because their apps have abetted the simplification of
investing for novices (Dave, 2020).
Both Robinhood and Webull are commission-free brokerages requiring no
account minimums. One can trade stocks and options, and cryptocurrencies as
well as Exchange Traded Funds. Whereas Robinhood presently deals with
individual brokerage accounts, Webull offers these, as well as, traditional and
Roth IRA’s (Dave, 2020).
While E*Trade, a full-service brokerage house was listed as Nerd Wallet’s Best
Investment Broker of April 2021, TD Ameritrade was ranked 2nd; Robinhood,
3rd; and Webulll, 6th of the top 11 ranked by this source (Davis, 2021). Table 1
lists the fees for various services offered by TD Ameritrade, Robinhood and
Webull.
Table 1.
Trading Fees for Services Offered by Ameritrade, Robinhood and Webull
(20 March 2020).
Feature
Ameritrade
Webull
Robinhood
Minimum deposit
$0.00
$0.00
$0.00
Stock trade fee (per trade)
$0.00
$0.00
$0.00
ETF trade fee
$0.00
$0.00
$0.00
Mutual fund trade fee
$49.99
N/A
N/A
Options base fee
$0.00
$0.00
$0.00
Options per contract fee
$0.65
$0.00
$0.00
Futures (per contract)
$2.25
N/A
N/A
Broker assisted trade fee
$4.99
N/A
N/A
Source:
Dave (2020) and Mirani (2021).
200
Studies in Microeconomics 11(2)
You will note that, unlike Ameritrade, Robinhood and Webull do not provide
for trading in mutual funds. Nor do Robinhood and Webull provide for trading in
futures, which is provided by Ameritrade. Also, as full-service brokerage firm,
Ameritrade gives the broker assistance to investors for a fee. Finally, Ameritrade
charges a per contract fee for options.
Similar fee structures for the many other discount brokers have contributed
that much more to the increase of accounts and users of the services offered by
those dealers.
Free-Enterprise Economics Illustrated in Ameritrade’s
Experience
Ameritrade is, of course, one example of many wild success stories in our free-
enterprise economy that have unfolded over our country’s nearly 250-year history.
Joe Ricketts started the company on precious little but ended up leaving it as a
very rich man nearly 30 years later. He was willing and eager to assume risks and
implement innovations in the creative destruction of stock trading. The experience
of Ameritrade provides many examples of the beauty of the free-enterprise market
system at work. Recall that when the government decided to phase out fixed
commissions on stock trades, most brokers virtually ignored the opportunity to
implement negotiated commissions, thinking that they would not be hurt as long
as they continued the policy of fixed commissions. However, Ricketts reasoned
that seizing this new-found opportunity to lower prices (commissions) would, as
the market predicts, attract additional customers. He wanted to be the first to crack
the old system, to innovate by using negotiated commissions to increase the
demand for his services (shifting it out to the right).
The large increase in Ameritrade’s trades after the company employed
negotiable commissions alluded to above suggests that the demand for trades is
price (commissions) elastic, that is, the percentage increase in trades is greater
than the percentage change in price (commission). This high elasticity is primarily
due to two factors. First, the number of available substitutes for shares traded is
quite large. This degree of substitutability is the most significant determinant of
price elasticity of demand, with elasticity for a good or service increasing with the
availability of substitutes. Obviously, in the general sense, one can choose to
purchase any one of a large number of goods and services with the money spent
on stock purchases. Even if one confines the purchaser’s choices to stocks or other
financial instruments, the alternatives are still plentiful.
In addition, the price of each trade, especially in the realm of ‘discount trading’
is usually relatively small as is the total amount spent on each trade. That is,
whether one purchases one share of a stock or several shares, the percentage of
one’s total income spent on a trade is relatively low. The smaller the percentage of
total income (or one’s budget) spent on the stock transactions, the higher is the
price (commission) elasticity of demand. Further, the large increase in accounts
gained by Ameritrade after its advertising efforts alluded to previously also
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
Greco
201
suggest a high advertising elasticity, with the percentage change in the gaining of
new accounts exceeding the percentage increase in advertising expenditures.
As indicated above, Ameritrade relied on advertising and technology from its
inception to generate new accounts and that in the 1990s it sought to achieve this
same objective by combining these with the acquisition of small competitors. The
phasing out of fixed commissions on stock trades initiated by the federal
government in 1995, as mentioned previously, provided an opportunity for
Ameritrade to enter and prosper in the discount-trading market and spurred its use
of advertising. Prior to this rule change, the large natural brokerages, as Ricketts
notes, had bought out small local firms and enjoyed financial and other economies
of scale which served as barriers to entry to smaller firms (Ricketts, 2019, p. 58).
Herein was a classic example of the dominant firm in an oligopolistic industry
surrounded by a large number of small firms benefiting from these barriers to
entry. This ‘disruptive’ rule change, hence, lessened the impact of a regulatory
barrier to entry. Ameritrade seized upon this opportunity and made a significant
entry into discount trading by using and advertising negotiable commissions in
their trades.
The firm sought to achieve economies of scale by expanding trading through
advertising. Advertising does not necessarily lead to economies of scale. Consider
Figure 1.
Some advertising may be described as ‘defensive advertising’, undertaken in
order to maintain a firm’s sales in response to the advertising of a firm’s
competitors. In
Figure 1, the lower curve,
AC
1
, indicates that the firm is not
advertising. Hence its average cost curve (
AC
1
) includes only the cost of
production. If the firm advertises, its average cost curve shifts up to
AC
2
, inclusive
of production and the advertising costs. If the firm is only able to maintain its
Figure 1.
Possible Effects of Advertising.
Source:
The author.
202
Studies in Microeconomics 11(2)
sales at
Q
1
and no more, the firm’s costs rise from point ‘a’ to point ‘b’ reflecting
higher costs at the firm’s scale of plant and, hence no economies of scale are
achieved.
If the firm’s sales soar from
A
1
to
AC
2
its costs would rise from point ‘a’ to
point ‘d’, clearly placing the firm in the diseconomies of scale region. If sales,
however, increase from
A
1
to
A
3
, the firm’s costs move from point ‘a’ to point ‘c’.
Here the firm is experiencing economies of scale at a large scale of plant.
In regard to Ameritrade’s advertising, the defensive advertising outcome of
moving from point ‘a’ to point ‘b’ is actually not relevant, for its competitive
brokerage houses were essentially not participating in discount trading. Ameritrade
was breaking new ground by offering trades in this third market at reduced
commissions. Therefore, Ameritrade’s accounts and number of trades would be
expected to increase, moving the firm from point ‘a’ to point ‘c’ due to its
advertising efforts. Seeing this expansion, Ameritrade’s competition, especially
the large ones, would respond by entering this market through their own advertising
efforts, as well as, by the acquisition of small brokers.
Figure 2 illustrates what occurs when economies of scale are actually achieved
through advertising.
Initially, it is assumed that the monopolistically competitive long-run
equilibrium position of normal profit is attained at point ‘a’ where price equals
P
1
and quantity per unit of time equals
Q
1
. The firm depicted above is not initially
engaging in advertising. Stock trading was, at this time, a monopolistically
competitive industry with many firms, mostly small, selling or providing a similar,
but not identical service. It eventually became the oligopolistic industry alluded to
above with an oligopolistic core of the large, full-service firm’s surrounded by a
‘competitive’ fringe of small firms. It gravitated to this condition after the
acquisition of smaller firms by the large firms, such as Dean Witter and
subsequently by the growing Ameritrade firm.
Figure 2.
Relationships of Advertising to Prices.
Source:
Industrial Organization, Clarkson and Miller, p.217.
Greco
203
If this firm initiates a successful advertising programme, the demand curve
above can shift to
D
2
resulting in lowering of costs from point ‘a’ to point ‘b’ with
a lower price,
P
2
, and a higher quantity,
Q
2
. Economies of scale are, hence,
achieved. This result occurs only if total demand in the industry increases or if
some firms depart from the industry. It does not apply if the advertising only
leads to an increase in demand for the advertising firm and a reduction in demand
for other firms in the industry (Clarkson & Miller, pp. 216–217). As an illustration
of an industry in which advertising led to lower prices, Muris and McChesney
(1979) found that advertising by legal clinics who could provide specialized
services capable of mass production led to a reduction in the prices charged by
the clinics (Clarkson & Miller, 1982, p. 219). Regarding his massive advertising,
Ricketts declared that the heralding of his eight-dollar pricing had exceeded his
expectations and allowed his firm to achieve the economies of scale he sought
(Ricketts, 2019, p. 264).
Amertirade’s clearing operations, as discussed above, provided a discount
wholesalers to a growing number of small brokers attracted by Ameritrade’s low
pricing policy. Such a policy was aided by the fact that Ameritrade was able to
charge such customers for other banking retail services, such as, margin loans and
stock lending. Hence, this vertical integration of Ameritrade into this wholesaling
function helped it to establish and maintain its low-commission policy and
ultimately aided the firm in achieving the desired economies of scale. The
innovative technology and business practices introduced by Ameritrade under the
direction of Ricketts, of course, also led to the expansion of the firm enabling it to
reach the economies of scale.
Summary and Conclusions
Joe Ricketts’ 2019 memoir of his business adventures and ultimate success in
Ameritrade, is interesting in and of itself. This study traced these elements rather
briefly. It was not intended to rehash all that Ricketts described. Nor was this
study intended to be a critique of his book. Rather, highlights of Ameritrade’s
story were summarized herein to give the reader a background before discussing
the economic implications of that story.
Obviously, the main takeaway from Ricketts’ memoir is that success can be
achieved and fortunes made in a free-enterprise market economy today, as in the
past, when one is willing to assume risks and commit time, other resources and
money in expanding a market of an existing product or service, in ‘creating’ a
market for a new product or service, or in devising new technology(ies) that
service one or the other. Such developments actually ‘destroy’ existing market(s)
and economic conditions. Hence, the term ‘creative destruction’.
Clearly, Joe Ricketts was a risk-taker and an innovative entrepreneur who was
willing to take chances. Like most entrepreneurs, he found risk-taking to be
exciting and invigorating. He innovated by introducing what came to be called
‘discount trading’ in the open or third market for stock trading. He also innovated
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
204
Studies in Microeconomics 11(2)
in stock trading by using touch-tone trading and continually improved technology
(computerized online trading).
Ameritrade’s experience also illustrates that such innovations can result in an
increase in demand for an existing product or the creation of demand for a new
product or service. Recall how the number of the firm’s accounts surged as it
inaugurated discount trading and, still further, as it introduced online trading.
Another accompanying innovation by Ameritrade was its exploration into
negotiated commissions in place of the traditional fixed commissions. This
facilitated into implementation of discount trading. This, indeed, was a novel and
risky approach, one that other existing brokers would not broach. This low-price
strategy illustrates the basic microeconomic concept of price elasticity of demand.
That is, the firm’s amount (quantity) of accounts increased significantly when the
price (commission) offered was reduced, that is, quantity demanded increased as
price was lowered.
The high advertising elasticity of demand was also revealed in Ameritrade’s
large expansion of advertising expenditures which greatly expanded its business.
This expansion powered the firm’s attainment of significant economies of scale.
The firm’s expanded commitment to technology, noted alone, together with its
eventual acquisitions of smaller competitors also contributed to the firm’s gaining
of economies of scale.
Yet another contributing factor to Ameritrade’s expansion and attainment of
economies of scale was its vertical integration into the wholesale aspect of market
clearing which allowed it to diversify into the provision of retail banking services
to smaller brokerage firms. Hence, Ameritrade’s story is fraught with examples of
textbook economics. It is an optimistic and positive story which can surely give
encouragement to prospective entrepreneurs today. It says that they can still
achieve great success when ‘thinking outside the box’ in developing new niches
and then having the vision to implement their brainchild.
Hence, the main takeaway from Joe Ricketts’ Ameritrade experience is that
free-enterprise markets can be expanded and made more efficient and that new
markets can be generated through the use of innovative ideas and technology.
Ricketts energized trading markets by introducing such innovations as discount
trades, online trades, negotiated trades, etc. Further, the effectiveness of his lower-
price policy, as well as his increased advertising, vividly illustrate both the
relatively high price elasticity of demand and high advertising elasticity of demand
for stock trades. Finally, Ameritrade’s vertical integration into market clearing
displayed the possibility of attaining further economies of scale.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests
The author declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship
and/or publication of this article.
Funding
The author received no financial support for the research, authorship and/or publication of
this article.
Greco
205
ORCID iD
Anthony J. Greco
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-0828-1508
References
Clarkson, K. W., & Miller, R. L. (1982).
Industrial organization: Theory, evidence, and
public policy
. McGraw and Hill Book Company.
Dave. (2020, March 20). Webull vs Robinhood: Which free broker is better?
Day Trade
.
Davis, C. (2021, March 22). 11 Best discount brokers of April 2021.
Nerd Wallet
.
Folger, J. (2021, January 29). Robinhood vs TD Ameritrade. Investopedia.
Lemke, T. (2019, October 4). What are the largest discount brokerage firms?
The Balance
.
Mirani, S. (2021, April 20).
Webull Vs. TD Ameritrade: Compare Trading and Account
Fees of the Two Trading Platforms
. RepublicWorld.com
Muris, T., & McChesney, F. S. (1979). Advertising and the price and quantity of legal
services: The case for legal clinics.
American Bar Foundation Research Journal
,
4
(1),
179–207.
Ricketts, J. (2019).
The harder you work, the luckier you get: An entrepreneur’s memoir
.
Simon and Schuster.
Spiegel, H. W. (1971).
The growth of economic thought
. Prentice-Hall.
Related Documents
Recommended textbooks for you






Brief Principles of Macroeconomics (MindTap Cours...
Economics
ISBN:9781337091985
Author:N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:Cengage Learning
Recommended textbooks for you
- Brief Principles of Macroeconomics (MindTap Cours...EconomicsISBN:9781337091985Author:N. Gregory MankiwPublisher:Cengage Learning






Brief Principles of Macroeconomics (MindTap Cours...
Economics
ISBN:9781337091985
Author:N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:Cengage Learning