midterm_1B_with_answers
pdf
keyboard_arrow_up
School
New York University *
*We aren’t endorsed by this school
Course
9012
Subject
Economics
Date
Jan 9, 2024
Type
Pages
13
Uploaded by AdmiralRainMule13
ECON-UA 12 — Intermediate Macroeconomics
Professor: Jaroslav Boroviˇcka
TA: Hyein Han
Fall 2023
Sample midterm exam 1B — not for examination
Suggested solution
Do not turn this page until instructed!
Read the instructions below first.
Name:
Signature:
1. This is a
70 minute midterm exam
. It is worth
100 points
. This booklet contains
13
pages.
2. At the beginning, you have
3 minutes
to look through the exam. This time is not
counted in the examination time above. No writing or note-taking is allowed during
this period — only reading.
3. When the time is up, you have to stop writing and return the booklet to me within
exactly 1 minute. This is your responsibility.
4. The exam is closed book, no notes.
5.
No electronic devices are allowed
.
6. Use empty pages at the end as scratch paper. Material written on scratch paper will
not be considered for grading.
1
1
True or false? [24 points total]
For each of the following statements, decide whether it is true or false, and
explain your
answer in at most two sentences using the material you learned in the course
. No points
will be given without an appropriate explanation!
Question 1.1
[3 points]
GDP per capita is not a useful measure of well-being because it has
little to do with reasonable indicators of life quality like life expectancy, absolute poverty
or health.
Answer
FALSE. On the contrary, we have seen plenty of empirical evidence
that GDP correlates with many of other measures of well-being. Countries that
are rich also have high life-expectancy, measures of health, education, etc.
Question 1.2
[3 points]
Under perfect competition, firms earn zero economic profits. The
value of the stock market under perfect competition should therefore be zero.
Answer
FALSE. Economic and accounting profits are different concepts—
accounting profits, for instance, include payments to all factors of production
that the firm owns (both tangible and intangible capital). Therefore, even un-
der perfect competition, the value of the stock market (which is the present
discounted value of accounting profits) can and will be nonzero.
Question 1.3
[3 points]
The model of production could not explain the differences in output
per capita across countries through the differences in capital per capita.
However, the
Solow growth model was much more successful in explaining the difference in output per
capita through differences in saving rates.
Answer
FALSE. Differences in saving rates in the Solow growth model ex-
plained even less of the differences in output per capita than differences in
capital per capita.
Question 1.4
[3 points]
In the Solow growth model, there is no money, so households have
no way of saving for the future.
Answer
FALSE. In the Solow growth model, households save by accumulat-
ing real resources, represented by the capital stock.
Question 1.5
[3 points]
If the labor share was close to zero, then the model of production
with Cobb–Douglas production technology would be able to explain the differences in
output per capita through differences in capital per capita.
Answer
TRUE. The Cobb–Douglas production technology implies the rela-
tionship
ln
y
=
ln
A
+
α
ln
k
.
2
We have observed that in the data, ln
k
and ln
y
are roughly linearly related,
with slope about one. When labor share is close to zero, then
α
in the produc-
tion technology is close to one, and would line up with empirical evidence.
Question 1.6
[3 points]
In the steady state of the Solow growth model, investment equals
depreciation, therefore the saving rate must equal the depreciation rate.
Answer
FALSE. The steady state relationship is
δ
K
∗
=
sY
∗
, not
δ
=
s
.
Question 1.7
[3 points]
Fast growth through capital accumulation induced by high saving
rates is unambiguously good for the households in the economy.
Answer
FALSE. As we have discussed in the lecture and in Paul Krugman’s
article ‘
The Myth of Asia’s Miracle
’ (
Krugman
(
1994
)), high saving rates implies
sacrificed consumption today. This is a sacrifice for the current generation that
future generations will benefit from.
Question 1.8
[3 points]
Increasing returns to scale imply that the marginal product of
capital is constant or increasing in
K
.
Answer
FALSE. These two concepts are not directly related. For instance, the
production functions
F
(
K
,
L
)
=
K
2/3
L
1/2
F
(
K
,
L
)
=
KL
1/2
F
(
K
,
L
)
=
K
3/2
L
1/2
all exhibit increasing returns to scale (sum of the exponents larger than one) but
the first has decreasing, the second constant, and the third increasing marginal
product of capital.
3
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
2
Growth rates and returns to scale [13 points total]
Question 2.1
[3 points]
The Cobb–Douglas production function is given by
Y
=
F
(
K
,
L
) =
AK
α
L
β
where
A
,
α
,
β
are strictly positive parameters. What restrictions do the parameters have to
satisfy so that the production function exhibits constant returns to scale?
When these restrictions are satisfied, is the marginal product of capital increasing, con-
stant, or decreasing in
K
?
Provide calculations for both questions.
Answer
We have
F
(
2
K
, 2
L
) =
A
(
2
K
)
α
(
2
L
)
β
=
2
α
+
β
F
(
K
,
L
)
and hence we require
β
=
1
−
α
. Under these restrictions
MPK
=
∂
∂
K
F
(
K
,
L
) =
α
AK
α
−
1
L
1
−
α
which is a decreasing function of capital.
Question 2.2
[4 points]
Consider the production function given by
Y
=
F
(
K
,
L
) =
aK
α
+
bL
β
where
a
,
b
,
α
,
β
are strictly positive parameters. What restrictions do the parameters have
to satisfy so that the production function exhibits constant returns to scale?
When these restrictions are satisfied, is the marginal product of capital increasing, con-
stant, or decreasing in
K
?
Provide calculations for both questions.
Answer
We have
F
(
2
K
, 2
L
) =
a
(
2
K
)
α
+
b
(
2
L
)
β
=
2
α
aK
α
+
2
β
bL
β
and hence we need
α
=
1 and
β
=
1. With these restrictions,
MPK
=
∂
∂
K
F
(
K
,
L
) =
a
and hence the production function exhibits a constant marginal product of cap-
ital.
Question 2.3
[6 points]
Consider growth in an economy with Cobb–Douglas production
4
function
Y
t
=
A
t
K
α
t
L
1
−
α
t
.
Assume that there are two countries,
C
and
D
. They both have the same growth rate of TFP,
denoted
g
A
, and the same growth rate of capital,
g
K
. Country
C
has a higher population
growth rate than country
D
,
g
C
L
>
g
D
L
.
Which of the two countries will have a higher growth rate of total output?
Which of the two countries will have a higher growth rate of output per capita?
Provide calculations (including the derivation of the output growth rate) for both
questions
.
Answer
The growth rate of total output is obtained by computing
1
+
g
K
=
Y
t
+
1
Y
t
=
A
t
+
1
K
α
t
+
1
L
1
−
α
t
+
1
A
t
K
α
t
L
1
−
α
t
=
A
t
+
1
A
t
K
t
+
1
K
t
α
L
t
+
1
L
t
1
−
α
=
(
1
+
g
A
) (
1
+
g
K
)
α
(
1
+
g
L
)
1
−
α
and the logarithmic approximation yields
g
Y
=
g
A
+
α
g
K
+ (
1
−
α
)
g
L
The growth rate of output per capita is then given by
g
y
=
g
Y
−
g
L
=
g
A
+
α
g
K
−
α
g
L
Hence, country
C
has a higher growth rate of total output
g
C
Y
−
g
D
Y
= (
1
−
α
)
g
C
L
−
g
D
L
>
0
but a lower growth rate of output per capita
g
C
y
−
g
D
y
=
−
α
g
C
L
−
g
D
L
<
0.
5
3
Stock market investment and arbitrage [23 points total]
Consider an investor who can invest into the stock market or into a savings account.
• If she invests into the stock market, she buys one stock at price
p
s
,
t
, earns dividend
d
t
and can sell the stock back at price
p
s
,
t
+
1
next period.
• Alternatively, she can invest the same resources into a (risk-free) savings account that
earns a (net) interest rate
R
.
Question 3.1
[3 points]
Set up the arbitrage equation that equalizes the profit from both
investments. Denote
p
s
,
t
+
1
−
p
s
,
t
as
Δ
p
s
,
t
+
1
.
Answer
We have
Rp
s
,
t
=
−
p
s
,
t
+
d
t
+
p
s
,
t
+
1
=
Δ
p
s
,
t
+
1
+
d
t
where the left-hand side is the profit from investing into a savings account,
while the right-hand side is the profit from the stock investment.
Question 3.2
[3 points]
Explain (in not more than two sentences) what is the economic
interpretation of the arbitrage equation.
Answer
The arbitrage equation represents the fact that in order for investors
to be indifferent between investing into the savings account and into the stock
market, the profits from the two investments must be the same.
Question 3.3
[5 points]
Divide the arbitrage equation by
p
s
,
t
and solve for the price-
dividend ratio
p
s
,
t
/
d
t
(in other words, derive the Gordon growth formula).
Make the
simplifying assumption that the growth rate of the stock price
Δ
p
s
,
t
+
1
/
p
s
,
t
is equal to the
dividend growth rate
g
d
.
Answer
Dividing by
p
s
,
t
, we get
R
=
Δ
p
s
,
t
+
1
p
s
,
t
+
d
t
p
t
.
p
s
,
t
d
t
=
1
R
−
Δ
p
s
,
t
+
1
p
s
,
t
=
1
R
−
g
d
.
Question 3.4
[4 points]
Empirically, investment into safe instruments like the savings ac-
count earns on average about 1% annual real return (this is
R
in our notation above). On
the other hand, investing into the broad stock market (like the S&P500 index) earns an
average annual real return of about 6%. Does this constitute an arbitrage opportunity?
Explain.
6
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
If it does constitute an arbitrage opportunity, what should investors do to take advan-
tage of it?
If it does not constitute an arbitrage opportunity, how should we properly interpret the
interest rate
R
in the arbitrage equation?
Answer
This does not constitute an arbitrage opportunity because these are
not comparable investments—investing into stocks is riskier. Hence the proper
interest rate is one that includes compensation for stock market risk, called the
risk premium. Hence
R
=
risk-free rate
+
risk premium.
Question 3.5
[3 points]
Consider the opportunity to invest into two stocks,
A
and
B
. If
stock
A
is considered to be riskier than stock
B
, what does the Gordon growth formula
imply for the price-dividend ratio of stock
A
compared to stock
B
?
Answer
The riskier stock
A
should earn a higher risk premium, hence a higher
R
. This implies that the price-dividend ratio
p
s
,
t
d
t
=
1
R
−
g
d
should be lower for stock
A
.
Question 3.6
[5 points]
Let
g
s
be the annual growth rate of the stock price, and
g
d
the
annual growth rate of the dividend. Show that if these growth rates are not the same (over
long periods of time), then the price dividend ratio
p
s
,
t
/
d
t
will either grow to infinity or
decline to zero.
Empirically, how does the price-dividend ratio behave over long periods of time?
Answer
The one-period growth rate of the price-dividend ratio is
p
s
,
t
+
1
/
d
t
+
1
p
s
,
t
/
d
t
=
p
s
,
t
+
1
p
s
,
t
d
t
d
t
+
1
=
1
+
g
s
1
+
g
d
.
Over the course of
T
years, this accumulates to
1
+
g
s
1
+
g
d
T
This is a geometric sequence in
T
. When
g
s
>
g
d
, then the coefficient
1
+
g
s
1
+
g
d
is
larger than one and the sequence diverges to infinity. When
g
s
<
g
d
, then the
coefficient
1
+
g
s
1
+
g
d
is smaller than one and the sequence converges to zero.
Empirically, the price-dividend ratio is roughly stationary (oscillates around
a stable level), and hence over long periods of time, we have to have
g
s
≈
g
d
.
7
4
Economic policies in the Solow growth model [40 points total]
Consider the Solow growth model, described by equations
Y
t
=
AK
α
t
L
1
−
α
Δ
K
t
+
1
=
sY
t
−
δ
K
t
Question 4.1
[2 points]
Using the equations above, state the steady state condition (one-
line answer).
Answer
The condition is
sY
∗
=
δ
K
∗
.
Question 4.2
[6 points]
Solve the steady state condition for the steady state level of cap-
ital
K
∗
as a function of parameters of the model. (
Hint
: Substitute out output using the
production function.)
Further determine the steady state level of output
Y
∗
and the steady state level of out-
put per capita
y
∗
as functions of model parameters.
Answer
We have
sA
(
K
∗
)
α
L
1
−
α
=
δ
K
∗
and thus
K
∗
=
sA
δ
1
1
−
α
L
.
To determine the steady state level of output, substitute
K
∗
into the production
function. Then
Y
∗
=
A
(
K
∗
)
α
L
1
−
α
=
A
sA
δ
α
1
−
α
L
=
A
1
1
−
α
s
δ
α
1
−
α
L
.
and
y
∗
=
Y
∗
L
=
A
1
1
−
α
s
δ
α
1
−
α
.
(4.1)
We are now interested in studying some proposed economic policies that you may
have heard of on national news. (Bear in mind that what we consider here are simpli-
fied abstractions that capture some but definitely not all of the impacts of the proposed
policies.)
Question 4.3
[5 points]
Presidential candidate
D
proposes to deport a part of the residing
population, thus decreasing the population size from
L
to
L
′
(the proposal is to do it very
quickly, which we approximate here as an instant change).
Sketch the Solow diagram (with the stock of capital on the horizontal axis), including
8
Y
sY
δ
K
K
∗
Y
′
sY
′
K
∗′
◀
capital
K
Y
,
I
,
δ
K
Figure 1: The Solow diagram for question
4.3
.
curves for output, depreciation and investment (saving). Appropriately label everything.
Depict the steady state level of capital,
K
∗
. In this diagram, clearly depict the impact of
the proposed policy by shifting the relevant curves. Depict the new steady state level of
capital
K
∗′
.
Answer
The answer is in Figure
1
. The decrease in population proportionally
scales the output function from
Y
=
AK
α
L
1
−
α
to
Y
′
=
AK
α
(
L
′
)
1
−
α
. The saving
(investment) function is scaled down accordingly.
The steady state level of
capital decreases.
Question 4.4
[6 points]
Plot the trajectory (time path) of the following variables:
• capital
• output per capita
• net investment
Specifically, assume that the economy starts in the original steady state, and the policy
is implemented at time
t
0
. Depict the original steady state, transition path, and the new
steady state.
Answer
The answer is in Figure
2
. The decrease in population occurs at time
t
0
. After the decline in population, the economy starts decumulating capital
toward the new steady state
K
∗′
. Output per capita increases on impact. To see
this, notice that
y
=
Ak
α
.
9
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
K
∗
K
∗′
t
0
time
t
K
t
y
∗
t
0
time
t
y
t
0
t
0
time
t
N
t
Figure 2: Trajectories for capital
K
t
, output per capita
y
t
and net investment
N
t
=
sY
t
−
δ
K
t
for Question
4.4
.
In the moment of the impact of the policy, capital per capita increases abruptly,
because population falls and capital stays the same at that moment (it is a stock
variable). Therefore, output per capita increases as well. However, over time,
output per capita has to converge back to the original steady state because
y
∗
does not depend on
L
(see equation (
4.1
)).
Net investment falls on impact of the policy, which starts off the process of
capital decumulation. Over time, net investment converges back to zero, as it
has to be zero in the new steady state.
Question 4.5
[4 points]
The proposed policy, if implemented fully, may decrease the pop-
ulation by about 2%, i.e.,
L
′
L
=
1
+
g
L
where
g
L
is the percentage change in population, with
g
L
=
−
0.02
=
−
2%. Compute the
percentage change in
total capital
and in
output per capita
that occurs
• immediately at the moment of implementation of the policy (short run effect, before
capital adjusts),
• between the old and new steady states (long run effect, after capital adjusts).
Hint
: To compute the short run effect, for instance, for the output per capita, evaluate
the ratio
y
′
/
y
where
y
is given by the Cobb–Douglas production function (in per capita
terms) before the policy change and
y
′
after the policy change. Denote this ratio as 1
+
g
y
and then take the logarithmic approximation to compute
g
y
as a function of
g
L
. For
the long-run effect, proceed in the same way to evaluate
y
∗′
/
y
∗
using the formula for the
steady state output per capita.
Answer
To compute the short run effects, first notice that there is no short run
effect on total capital, because capital is a state variable. Further
y
′
y
=
A
(
k
′
)
α
Ak
α
=
k
′
k
α
=
K
/
L
′
K
/
L
α
=
L
′
L
−
α
10
and therefore
1
+
g
y
=
(
1
+
g
L
)
−
α
g
y
≈
−
α
g
L
Therefore, a 2% decrease in
L
leads to a 2
α
%
=
2
3
% short-run increase in output
per capita.
The long-run effect on total capital is
K
∗′
K
∗
=
(
sA
δ
)
1
1
−
α
L
′
(
sA
δ
)
1
1
−
α
L
and hence
g
K
=
g
L
. In the long run, total capital decreases by 2%. The long-run
effect on output per capita is zero, since (
4.1
) shows that
y
∗
does not depend
on
L
.
Question 4.6
[2 points]
Presidential candidate
H
proposes to increase taxation of capital
income. Here, we implement the capital tax as a fraction
τ
K
of capital that firms have to pay
to the government
every period
. For simplicity, we assume that the firm receives nothing
in return and the resources paid to the government are destroyed.
Modify the law of motion for capital to incorporate the policy into the model. Show
that the introduction of the capital tax is equivalent to an increase in the depreciation rate
to
δ
′
. What is the relationship between
δ
and
δ
′
?
Answer
Now we have
Δ
K
t
+
1
=
sY
t
−
δ
K
t
−
τ
K
K
t
=
sY
t
−
(
δ
+
τ
K
)
|
{z
}
δ
′
K
t
.
Question 4.7
[5 points]
Sketch a
NEW
Solow diagram, including curves for output, depre-
ciation and investment. Appropriately label everything. In this diagram, clearly depict the
impact of the proposed policy by shifting the relevant curves. Depict the new steady state
level of capital
K
∗′
Answer
The answer is in Figure
3
. The increase in tax rate (which is equivalent
to an increase in the depreciation rate to
δ
′
=
δ
+
τ
K
increases the slope of the
‘depreciation’ function (which now included the tax payments). The steady
state level of capital decreases.
Question 4.8
[6 points]
Plot the trajectory (time path) of the following variables:
• capital
11
Y
sY
δ
K
K
∗
δ
′
K
K
∗′
◀
capital
K
Y
,
I
,
δ
K
Figure 3: The Solow diagram for question
4.7
.
K
∗
K
∗′
t
0
time
t
K
t
y
∗
y
∗′
t
0
time
t
y
t
0
t
0
time
t
N
t
Figure 4: Trajectories for capital
K
t
, output per capita
y
t
and net investment
N
t
=
sY
t
−
δ
K
t
for Question
4.8
.
• output per capita
• net investment
Specifically, assume that the economy starts in the original steady state, and the policy
is implemented at time
t
0
. Depict the original steady state, transition path, and new steady
state.
Answer
The answer is in Figure
4
. Capital and output per capita decrease to
a lower steady state. Net investment falls abruptly and then converges back to
zero.
Question 4.9
[4 points]
Briefly comment (not more than four sentences) on the benefits and
costs of these two policies that the Solow growth model reveals. Are the households (those
12
Your preview ends here
Eager to read complete document? Join bartleby learn and gain access to the full version
- Access to all documents
- Unlimited textbook solutions
- 24/7 expert homework help
who remain in the economy) better off in the short run? In the long run?
Again, your answers should reflect the effects that the Solow model predicts.
You
should bear in mind that this is not a complete description of the overall impact of the
policies. The purpose of this exercise is to clearly expose one particular channel (capital
accumulation in the Solow model) through which policies impact the economy.
Answer
We can measure well-being in terms of consumption per capita. Since
consumption per capita is a fraction 1
−
s
of output per capita, we can focus on
output per capita.
The ‘
D
policy’ improves the well-being in the short run, since deported
population leaves capital behind, which increases the capital per capita for
the remaining population. This also temporarily increases output per capita.
However, the economy starts decumulating capital, so that in the long run, the
households are equally well off as before.
The ‘
H
policy’ leads to capital decumulation without a temporary increase
in output per capita. The long-run steady state is lower than the initial steady
state, which makes households worse off.
Of course, we neglected many aspects of these policies that would be rele-
vant for the evaluation of the overall effect. Deportations would be costly, the
country may be using specific types of workers which are hard to replace by
existing workforce, etc. The proceeds from capital taxation are typically not
destroyed but the government can use them to finance government expendi-
tures. They also may have appealing redistributional effects. These are just
some examples of some other effects that one should consider.
References
Krugman, Paul. 1994. “The Myth of Asia’s Miracle.”
Foreign Affairs
73 (6):62–78.
13
Recommended textbooks for you

Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an...
Economics
ISBN:9781305506381
Author:James R. McGuigan, R. Charles Moyer, Frederick H.deB. Harris
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Economics Today and Tomorrow, Student Edition
Economics
ISBN:9780078747663
Author:McGraw-Hill
Publisher:Glencoe/McGraw-Hill School Pub Co

Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:9781337106665
Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Microeconomics: Principles & Policy
Economics
ISBN:9781337794992
Author:William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. Solow
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Recommended textbooks for you
- Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an...EconomicsISBN:9781305506381Author:James R. McGuigan, R. Charles Moyer, Frederick H.deB. HarrisPublisher:Cengage LearningEconomics Today and Tomorrow, Student EditionEconomicsISBN:9780078747663Author:McGraw-HillPublisher:Glencoe/McGraw-Hill School Pub CoManagerial Economics: A Problem Solving ApproachEconomicsISBN:9781337106665Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike ShorPublisher:Cengage Learning
- Microeconomics: Principles & PolicyEconomicsISBN:9781337794992Author:William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. SolowPublisher:Cengage Learning

Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategies an...
Economics
ISBN:9781305506381
Author:James R. McGuigan, R. Charles Moyer, Frederick H.deB. Harris
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Economics Today and Tomorrow, Student Edition
Economics
ISBN:9780078747663
Author:McGraw-Hill
Publisher:Glencoe/McGraw-Hill School Pub Co

Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:9781337106665
Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:Cengage Learning

Microeconomics: Principles & Policy
Economics
ISBN:9781337794992
Author:William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder, John L. Solow
Publisher:Cengage Learning
